First five-year plan

First five-year plan

edit

The first five-year plan (Russian: I пятилетний план, первая пятилетка) of the Union of Soviet Socialist Republics (USSR) was a list of economic goals, created by Communist Party General Secretary Joseph Stalin, based on his policy of Socialism in One Country. The plan was implemented in 1928 and took effect until 1932[1].

The Soviet Union entered a series of five-year plans which began in 1928 under the rule of Joseph Stalin. Stalin launched what would later be referred as a "revolution from above" to improve the Soviet Union’s domestic policy. The policies were centered around rapid industrialization and the collectivization of agriculture. Stalin desired to remove and replace any policies created under the New Economic Policy[2].

The plan, overall, was to transition the Soviet Union from a weak, poorly controlled, agriculture state, into an industrial powerhouse[2]. While the vision was grand, its planning was ineffective and unrealistic given the short amount of time given to meet the desired goals.[3]

In 1929, Stalin edited the plan to include the creation of "kolkhoz" collective farming systems that stretched over thousands of acres of land and had hundreds of thousands of peasants working on them. The creation of collective farms essentially destroyed the kulaks as a class (dekulakization). Another consequence of this is that peasants resisted by killing their farm animals rather than turning them over to the State when their farms were collectivized.[4] Stalin's collectivization policies led to a famine in Ukraine, Russia, Kazakhstan as well as areas of the Northern Caucasus. Public machine and tractor stations were set up throughout the USSR, and peasants were allowed to use these public tractors to farm the land, increasing the food output per peasant. Peasants were allowed to sell any surplus food from the land. However, the government planners failed to take notice of local situations. In 1932, grain production was 32% below average;[5] to add to this problem, procurement of food increased by 44%. Agricultural production was so disrupted that famine broke out in several districts.[6]

Because of the plan's reliance on rapid industrialization, major cultural changes had to occur in tandem. As this new social structure arose, conflicts occurred among some of the majority of the populations. In Turkmenistan, for example, the Soviet policy of collectivization shifted their production from cotton to food products.[7] Such a change caused unrest within a community that had already existed prior to this external adjustment, and between 1928 and 1932, Turkmen nomads and peasants made it clear through methods like passive resistance that they did not agree with such policies.[7]

Reasoning for the first five-year plan

edit

Prior to launching the first Soviet five-year plan, the Soviet Union had been facing threats from external sources as well as experiencing an economic and industrial downturn since the introduction of Bolshevik rule.[8] The first war threat emerged from the East in 1924.[9] A war scare arose in 1927[10] when Western nations, like Great Britain, began cutting off diplomatic relations with the Soviet Union.[11] Soviets became fearful that the West was preparing to attack the Soviet Union again, as during the Russian Civil War foreign powers had occupied portions of Russian territory. The fear of invasion from the west left the Soviets feeling a need for rapid industrialization to increase Soviet war-making potential, and to compete with the western powers. One of the tasks of the five-year plan was to create all the necessary technical and economic prerequisites for increasing to the utmost the defense capacity of the country, enabling it to organize determined resistance to any attempt at military intervention from abroad, to any attempt at military attack from abroad[12]. During this time, the secret police (the OGPU) had begun rounding up political dissenters in the Soviet Union.[13] All these tensions had the potential to destroy the young Soviet Union. Thus, Joseph Stalin was forced to introduce rapid industrialization of heavy industry so that the Soviet Union could address external and internal threats if needed[14]

At the same time as the War Scare of 1927, dissatisfaction grew among the peasantry of the Soviet Union. This dissatisfaction arose from the famine of the early 1920s, as well as from increasing mistreatment of the peasants.[15] The Soviet Union was also dependent upon the caprices of the capitalist countries. Thus, Stalin desired to make the Soviet Union a country of self-reliance and independence. With industrialization, the Soviet Union could become a modern state. Stalin also desired the removal of any form of capitalism within agriculture. Prior to collectivization, the amount of food available often differentiated heavily in each region of the Soviet Union. Stalin's goal was to reorganize the entire process of agriculture[12].

Rapid growth of heavy industry

edit

The central aspect of the first Soviet five-year plan was the rapid industrialization of the Soviet Union from October 1928 to December 1932, which was thought to be the most crucial time for Russian industrialization.[16] Lenin himself before the time of his death, knew the importance of building a transitionary state to communism and was quoted saying "Modern industry is the key to this transformation, the time has come to construct our fatherland anew with the hands of machines."[17] Rapid Growth was facilitated starting in 1928 and continued to accelerate because of the building of heavy industry, which in turn raised living standards for peasants escaping the countryside.[18] The Bolsheviks' need for rapid industrialization was once again out of the fear of impending war from the West. If war were to break out between the Soviet Union and the West, the Soviets would be fighting against some of the most industrialized nations in the world. The rapid industrialization would inhibit fears of being left unprotected if War between the Soviets and the West were to occur. To meet the needs of a possible war, the Soviet leaders set unrealistic quotas for production.[19] To meet those unrealistic needs, the facilities had to be constructed quickly to facilitate material production before goods could be produced. During this period 1928-1932, massive industrial centers emerged in areas that were highly isolated before. These factories were not only for war production, but to produce tractors to meet the needs of mechanized agriculture. The Stalingrad Tractor Plant was built with the help of western allies and was meant to play a major factor in the rapid industrialization of Russia. These isolated areas included Magnitogorsk, Dnieper, and Nizhny Novgorod.[20] Magnitogorsk, the largest of the rapid industrialized areas of Russia, was founded in 1743, but became more prevalent in the early 1930's by Stalin. His plan was to make it a one-industry town. The city would become the largest steel producer in Russia and was meant to rival production that was being seen in the U.S. at the same time. During this era of Soviet history, heavy industry was supposed to experience a 350% increase in output.[19] The Soviet Union's achievements were tremendous during the first five year plan, which yielded a fifty-percent increase in industrial output[21] To achieve this massive economic growth, the Soviet Union had to reroute essential resources to meet the needs of heavy industry. 80% of the total investment of the first five-year plan, was focused heavily on the industrial sector. Programs not necessary to heavy industry were cut from the Soviet budget; and because of the redistribution of industrial funding, basic goods, such as food, became scarce.[22] The fact that the Great Depression was driving down the price of grain and other raw materials, which is most likely a result of Collectivization. The Soviet Union then decided that the workers necessary for further industrialization should be given most of the available food.[23] From this rapid industrialization a new working class emerged in the Soviet Union.[24] This new society was to be an industrial working class, which could be considered much of the population with the purpose of becoming a technologically advanced industry.[25] During this time the industrial workforce rose from 3.12 million in 1928 to 6.01 million at the end of the plan in 1932.[26] Behind the Urals,[27] a book by John Scott posed the question of the paranoia felt by the workers in these factories during the first five year plan. Forced labor became the norm because of propaganda scaring the workers by fear of the second coming of the Great Purge.

Agricultural collectivization

edit
 
The requisition of grains from wealthy peasants (kulaks) during the forced collectivization in Timashyovsky District, Kuban Soviet Union. 1933

Agricultural collectivization, within Russia, had its origins under Lenin during the New Economic Policy. One reason for the collectivization of Soviet agriculture was to increase the number of industrial workers for the new factories.[19] Soviet officials also believed that collectivization would increase crop yields and help fund other programs.[19] The Soviets enacted a land decree in 1917 that eliminated private ownership of land. Vladimir Lenin tried to establish removal of grain from wealthier peasants after the initial failure of state farms but this was also unsuccessful. Peasants were mainly concerned for their own well being and felt that the state had nothing of necessity to offer for the grain. This stockpiling of grain by the peasantry left millions of people in the city hungry, leading Lenin to establish his New Economic Policy to keep the economy from crashing. NEP was based more on capitalism and not socialism, which is the direction the country wanted to head toward. By 1928, with the rapid industrialization, and mass urbanization that followed, consumption was to increase rapidly as well. Need for urban dwellers to be fed, the FYP increased collectivization, leading to its recognition be largely associated with Stalin.[28] Beginning in 1929 under the FYP, mass collectivization was communal farms being assigned an amount of agricultural output with government coercion.[29] Villages had to agree to collectivization: some collectivization planners would hold endless meetings that would not end until villages joined; another tactic was through intimidation and coercion.[30] Mass agricultural collectivization was largely supported by the middle and poor peasantry [31] As the peasant class itself was divided into three groups: kulaks, wealthy; serednyak, middle; bednyak, poor. The middle and lower class supported collectivization, because it took private land from individual Kulak’s, and distributed it among the serednyak and bednyak’s villages. With the serednyak and bednyak joining collectivization they were also joining a kohloz. The kulaks did not support mass collectivization, as their land was being taken from them as well as their animals. At the end of 1929 the Soviets asserted themselves to forming collectivized peasant agriculture, but the “Kulaks” had to be “liquidated as a class,” because of their resistance to fixed agricultural prices.[32] Resulting from this, the party behavior became uncontrolled and manic when the party began to requisition food from the countryside.[32] Kulaks were executed, exiled or deported, based on their level of resistance to collectivization.[33] The kulaks who were considered "counter-revolutionary" were executed or exiled, those who opposed collectivization were deported to remote regions and the rest were resettled to non-arable land in the same region.[33] In the years following the agricultural collectivization, the reforms would disrupt the Soviet food supply.[32] In turn, this disruption would eventually lead to famines for the many years following the first five-year plan, with 6-7 million dying from starvation in 1933.[34]

Although Stalin reported in 1930 that collectivization was aiding the country, it must be noted that this was the era of exaggeration.[35] Collectivization was under-planned; a lack of instructions, and unrealistic quotas were the reality.[36] With lack of a foundation, collectivization led to the Famine of 1931-33 in Kazakhstan, the region once being a major grain producer.[37][38] Farmers of Kazakhstan rejected collectivization, and protested, while Stalin raised quotas, meaning peasants would not be able to eat and would psychologically break them. Those who did not give up their grain were considered breaking Soviet law, which caused the famine. Death rates are estimated between 6 - 7 million.[37] Stalin’s second wife Nadezhda Alliluyeva, committed suicide due to the atrocities of collectivization, particular the famine.[39] By the end of the FYP, agricultural collectivization showed minimal growth in production as well as profits, agricultural collectivization was a failure for the Soviets.

Prisoner labor

edit
 
Yakov Guminer's 1931 poster reading "The arithmetic of an industrial-financial counter-plan: 2 + 2 plus the enthusiasm of the workers = 5"

To meet the goals of the first five-year plan the Soviet Union began using the labor of its growing prisoner population. Initially the Soviet leaders sought to decrease the number of prisoners in the Soviet Union so that those resources could be rerouted to the five-year plan.[40] This legislation led to many dangerous prisoners being released from prison into labor camps.[41]

Early in the plan, however, the Communist leaders realized the necessity and the benefit of prisoner labor to complete the five-year plan. At this time the Soviet leaders attempted to orchestrate an increase in prison population.[40] The people of the Soviet Union began being sentenced to forced labor, even when they committed small offenses, or committed no crime at all.[41] Many of the prisoners used for labor were peasants who had resisted indoctrination.[42] This was an attempt by the Soviet Union to acquire free labor for the rapid industrialization; however, it led to the incarceration of many innocent people in the Soviet Union. Eventually Western nations, such as the United States, began to boycott goods produced by this form of labor.[43]

Successes of the first five-year plan

edit

Although many of the goals set by the plan were not fully met, there were several economic sectors that still saw large increases in their output. Areas like capital goods increased 158%, consumer goods increased by 87%, and total industrial output increased by 118%.[44] In addition, despite the difficulties that agriculture underwent throughout the plan, the Soviets recruited more than 70,000 volunteers from the cities to help collectivize and work on farms in the rural areas.[45]

The largest success of the first five-year plan, however, was the Soviet Union beginning its journey to become an economic and industrial superpower.[46] Stalin declared the plan a success at the beginning of 1933, noting the creation of several heavy industries where none had existed,[47] and that the plan was fulfilled in four years and three months instead of five years.[48] The plan was also lauded by some members of the Western media, and although much of his reporting was later disputed, New York Times reporter Walter Duranty received the 1932 Pulitzer Prize for Correspondence for his coverage of the first five-year plan. Duranty's coverage of the five-year plan's many successes led directly to Franklin Roosevelt officially recognizing the Soviet Union in 1933.[49]

The first five-year plan also began to prepare the Soviet Union to win in the Second World War. Without the initial five-year plan, and the ones that followed, the Soviet Union would not have been prepared for the German invasion in 1941. Due to the rapid industrialization of the plan, as well as the strategic construction of arms manufacturers in areas less vulnerable to future warfare,[50] the Soviet Union was able to build the weapons it needed to defeat the Germans in 1945.

Failures of the first five-year plan

edit

The first plan was destined for failure from the beginning because of unrealistic quotas set for industrialization that, in reality, would not be met for decades to come. The great push for industrialization caused quotas to consistently be looked at and adjusted. Quotas expecting to reach 235.9 percent output and labor to increase by 110 percent were unrealistic in the time frame they allotted for.[51] One of the problems was the goals for the plans were not set and those that were, were constantly changed.[52] Each time one quota was met, it was revised and made larger, which quickly eliminated any chance of the plan succeeding.[52] On top of that, work-life was rough since unions were being shut down which meant workers were no longer allowed to strike and not be protected from being fired or dismissed from work for reasons such as being late or just missing a day.[51]

 
Stamp commemorating the First Five Year plan depicts a man and woman working together in an industrial setting.

Secondly, the collectivization created a large-scale famine in the Soviet Union between 1932 and 1933 in which 3.3 to 7.5 million died.[34] These famines were among the worst in history and created scars which would mark the Soviet Union for many years to come and incense a deep hatred of Russians by Ukrainians, Tartars, and many other ethnic groups. This famine led many Russians to relocate to find food, jobs, and shelter outside of their small villages which caused many towns to become overpopulated. Their diet consisted of bread but there was a major decrease in the amount of meat and dairy they were receiving if any at all.[51] Aside from the three to four million people dying because of starvation or even freezing to death because of waiting in line for rations, people were not wanting or unable to have children which assisted in the decrease of the population.[53] Hitler used the disregard of human life by Russians toward non-Russians as one of his bases to conduct Operation Barbarossa and gain initial victories over the Russians. These failures would lead to the plan being discontinued after four years instead of five.[54]

Stalin’s vision and plan for Collectivization led to the death of millions of people due to famines and the imprisonment of others into labor camps. While some dangerous prisoners were released and forced into labor camps others were now set free in a failing economy with no work and no fair chance of survival and making ends meet. People were forced to live in communal apartments with many other families who also faced the horrors of being hungry, without work and the danger of being robbed for the possessions that they did manage to keep. With such living quarters people shared tight spaces with strangers accompanied by many other horrors such as theft, violence and stripped of privacy.

Legacy

edit

In Cities

edit

A number of streets and squares in major Russian cities are named after the plan, including the First Five-Year Plan Street in Chelyabinsk and Volgograd, and First Five-Year Plan Square in Yekaterinburg. The First Five Year Plan Saw Soviet Cities sharply rise in population. At least 23 million Soviet peasants moved into cities, with Moscow's population rising by nearly 60 percent.[55] A large portion of the Soviet Union's urbanization was due to the deportation of peasants from villages.[55] From 1929 through 1931, 1.4 million peasants were deported into cities.[55]

Cultural

edit

The Five Year Plan saw the expedited transformation of Soviet social relations, nature, and economy. The plan's greatest supporters viewed it as the means to change the Soviet Union economically and socially. This change was visibly seen in the role of women in the industrial workplace where rudimentary figures show they comprised 30 percent of the workforce.[56] The prevalence of women within the industrial workplace saw International Women's Day rise in significance in Soviet Culture.[56]

The Five Year Plans also saw a cultural change in the decline of the Kulak population within the Soviet Union.[56] Members of Agitprop brigands attempted to use the push towards industrialization to isolate peasants from religion and away from the formerly influential Kulak population with performances in which they would deem that issues faced by peasant populations were the faults of the Kulaks.[56] From 1929 through 1931, 3.5 million Kulaks were dispossessed by the Soviet Union and left with no choice but relocation to cities.[55]

State Investment

edit

As a result of the First Five Year Plan, state investment volume increased from 15% in 1928 to 44% in 1932 due to the rise in industry.[57] The First Five Year Plan resulted in the easy access of staple foods bread, potatoes and cabbage across the Soviet Union.[57] Severe drops in agriculture did however result in famine and inflation as agricultural output and livestock numbers in general dropped.[57]

Military

edit

Soviet reports from before the Five Year Plan found that much of the military production capacities in the Soviet Union lay in the country's war threatened Western provinces and notably the city of Leningrad.[58] In 1931 evacuation plans for military production facilities into deeper Soviet territories were drafted[58] beginning a policy that would accelerate and relocate deeper within the Soviet Union during World War II.

Film Industry

edit

Between 1929 and 1936 the Soviet Union shifted from producing solely silent films to solely sound films.[59] During this period the Soviet Government signed agreements with American, French and German companies to develop sound technology for Soviet cinema.[59]

See also

edit

References

edit
  1. ^ "The First Five Year Plan, 1928-1932". Special Collections & Archives. 2015-10-07. Retrieved 2019-02-23.
  2. ^ a b "The Results of the First Five-Year Plan". www.marxists.org. Retrieved 2019-02-24.
  3. ^ "Collectivization and Industrialization". www.loc.gov. Retrieved 2018-04-20.
  4. ^ "1929". Seventeen Moments in Soviet History. 2015-06-17. Retrieved 2018-03-25.
  5. ^ Robert Conquest, The Great Terror, 1971
  6. ^ R. W. Davies, Soviet History in the Gorbachev Revolution (Macmillan, London, 1989)
  7. ^ a b Edgar, Adrienne (2004). Tribal Nation. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. p. 296. ISBN 0-691-11775-6.
  8. ^ Florinsky, Michael (Aug 1953). "Soviet Economic Policies". ProQuest Politics Collection: 93–100.
  9. ^ Fitzpatrick, Sheila (1994). The Russian Revolution. Oxford: Oxford University Press. p. 120.
  10. ^ Hudson, Hugh (2012). "The 1927 Soviet War Scare: The Foreign Affairs-Domestic Policy Nexus Revisited". The Soviet and Post-Soviet Review. 39 (2): 1. doi:10.1163/18763324-03902002.
  11. ^ Morrell, Gordon W. (1995). Britain Confronts the Stalin Revolution: Anglo-Soviet Relations and the Metro-Vickers Crisis. Waterloo (Canada): Wilfrid Laurier University Press. p. 29. Google Preview for the book.
  12. ^ a b "The Results of the First Five-Year Plan". www.marxists.org. January 7, 1933.
  13. ^ Fitzpatrick, Sheila (1994). The Russian Revolution. Oxford: Oxford University Press. p. 121.
  14. ^ Hunter, Holland (June 1973). "The Overambitious First Soviet Five-Year Plan". Slavic Review. 32 (2): 237–257. doi:10.2307/2495959. JSTOR 2495959 – via JSTOR.
  15. ^ Hudson, Hugh (2012). "The 1927 Soviet War Scare: The Foreign Affairs-Domestic Policy Nexus Revisited". The Soviet and Post-Soviet Review. 39 (2): 1. doi:10.1163/18763324-03902002.
  16. ^ Davies, Robert (1994). The Economic Transformation of The Soviet Union, 1913-1945. ISBN 0521451523.
  17. ^ Fitzpatrick, Sheila (1999). Everyday Stalinism: Ordinary Life in Extraordinary Times. ISBN 0195050002.
  18. ^ Allen, Robert (1947). Farm to Factor: A Reinterpretation of the Soviet Industrial Revolution. ISBN 0691006962.
  19. ^ a b c d "Collectivization And Industrialization". Library of Congress. Retrieved April 17, 2014.
  20. ^ Fitzpatrick, Shelia (1994). The Russian Revolution. Oxford: Oxford University Press. p. 133.
  21. ^ Keefe, Joshua (2009). "Stalin and the Drive to Industrialize the Soviet Union". Inquires. 1 (10): 1.
  22. ^ Hansen, Stephen (1997). Time and Revolution: Marxism and the Design of Soviet Institutions. University Of North Carolina Press. p. 95.
  23. ^ Khrushchev, Nikita (2004). Memoirs of Nikita Khrushchev. Chapel Hill: Pennsylvania State University. p. 56.
  24. ^ Davies, Robert (1994). The Economic Transformation of the Soviet Union. New york: Cambridge University Press. p. 95.
  25. ^ Davies, Robert (1994). The Economical Transformation of the Soviet Union, 1913-1945. ISBN 0521451523.
  26. ^ Hansen, Stephen (1997). Time and Revolution: Marxism and the Design of Soviet Institutions. University Of North Carolina Press. p. 95.
  27. ^ Scott, John (1943). Behind the Ural: An American Worker in Russia's City of Steel. ISBN 978-0-253-20536-0.
  28. ^ Livi-Bacci, M. “On the Human Costs of Collectivization in the Soviet Union.” Population & Development Review, vol. 19, no. 4, 1993, p. 744., doi:10.2307/2938412.
  29. ^ Millar, James R. “Mass Collectivization and the Contribution of Soviet Agriculture to the First Five-Year Plan: A Review Article.” Slavic Review, vol. 33, no. 4, 1974, pp. 749., doi:10.2307/2494513.
  30. ^ Fitzpatrick, Sheila. “The Question of Social Support for Collectivization.” Russian History, vol. 37, no. 2, 2010, pp. 157-58., doi:10.1163/187633110X494670.
  31. ^ Fitzpatrick, Sheila. “The Question of Social Support for Collectivization.” Russian History, vol. 37, no. 2, 2010, pp. 153., doi:10.1163/187633110X494670.
  32. ^ a b c Fitzpatrick, Shelia (1994). The Russian Revolution. Oxford: Oxford University Press. p. 136.
  33. ^ a b McCauley, Martin (2013). Stalin and Stalinism. New York: Rutledge. p. 40.
  34. ^ a b Fitzpatrick, Shelia (2008). The Russian Revolution (3rd ed.). Oxford: Oxford University Press. p. 140.
  35. ^ Fitzpatrick, Sheila. Everyday Stalinism: Ordinary Life in Extraordinary Times – Soviet Russia in the 1930s. Oxford, England ; New York, New York: Oxford University Press, 1999.
  36. ^ Fitzpatrick, Sheila. “The Question of Social Support for Collectivization.” Russian History, vol. 37, no. 2, 2010, pp. 158., doi:10.1163/187633110X494670
  37. ^ a b Pianciola, N. “The Collectivization Famine in Kazakhstan, 1931-1933.” Harvard Ukrainian Studies, vol. 25, no. 3-4, 2001, p. 237.
  38. ^ Economakis, E. “Soviet Interpretations of Collectivization.” Slavonic and East European Review, vol. 69, no. 2, 1991, pp. 272
  39. ^ McCauley, Martin. Stalin and Stalinism. Pearson Longman, 2008.
  40. ^ a b Scherer, John (1993). "The collectivisation of agriculture and the Soviet prison camp system". Europe-Asia Studies. 45 (3): N26. doi:10.1080/09668139308412104.
  41. ^ a b Scherer, John (1993). "The collectivisation of agriculture and the Soviet prison camp system". Europe-Asia Studies. 45 (3): N31. doi:10.1080/09668139308412104.
  42. ^ Scherer, John (1993). "The collectivisation of agriculture and the Soviet prison camp system". Europe-Asia Studies. 45 (3): N35. doi:10.1080/09668139308412104.
  43. ^ Scherer, John (1993). "The collectivisation of agriculture and the Soviet prison camp system". Europe-Asia Studies. 45 (3): N49. doi:10.1080/09668139308412104.
  44. ^ Dobb, Maurice (2007). "Rates of growth under the five‐year plans". Soviet Studies. 4 (4): 364–385. doi:10.1080/09668135308409870. ISSN 0038-5859.
  45. ^ Millar, James R. (2017). "Mass Collectivization and the Contribution of Soviet Agriculture to the First Five-Year Plan: A Review Article". Slavic Review. 33 (4): 750–766. doi:10.2307/2494513. ISSN 0037-6779. JSTOR 2494513.
  46. ^ Hunter, Holland (2017). "The Overambitious First Soviet Five-Year Plan". Slavic Review. 32 (2): 237–257. doi:10.2307/2495959. ISSN 0037-6779. JSTOR 2495959.
  47. ^ Stalin, Joseph (7 January 1933). Joint Plenum of the C.C. and C.C.C., C.P.S.U.(B.) January 7–12, 1933: The Results of the First Five-Year Plan. Foreign Languages Publishing House, Moscow. Retrieved 29 March 2017.
  48. ^ Stalin, Joseph (1954). Works, Vol. 13, 1930 - January 1934. Moscow: Foreign Languages Publishing House. Retrieved 29 March 2017.
  49. ^ Taylor, Sally J. (1990). Stalin's Apologist. Oxford University Press.
  50. ^ Stone, David R. (2006). "The First Five-Year Plan and the Geography of Soviet Defence Industry". Europe-Asia Studies. 57 (7): 1047–1063. doi:10.1080/09668130500302756. ISSN 0966-8136. S2CID 153925109.
  51. ^ a b c F., Pauley, Bruce (2014). Hitler, Stalin, and Mussolini : Totalitarianism in the Twentieth Century (4th ed.). Hoboken: Wiley. ISBN 9781118765869. OCLC 883570079.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  52. ^ a b Fitzpatrick, Shelia (1994). The Russian Revolution. Oxford: Oxford University Press. p. 132.
  53. ^ Sheila., Fitzpatrick (1999). Everyday Stalinism : ordinary life in extraordinary times : Soviet Russia in the 1930s. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 9780195050011. OCLC 567928000.
  54. ^ Khrushchev, Nikita (2004). Memoirs of Nikita Khrushchev. Chapel Hill: Pennsylvania State University. p. XIV.
  55. ^ a b c d Hoffmann, David L. (Winter 1991). "Moving to Moscow: Patterns of Peasant In-Migration during the First Five- Year Plan". Slavic Review. 50 (4): 847–857. doi:10.2307/2500466. JSTOR 2500466 – via Cambridge University Press.
  56. ^ a b c d Mally, Lynn (Spring-Summer-Fall-Winter 1996). "Shock Workers on the Cultural Front: Agitprop Brigades in the First Five-Year Plan". Brill Online Journal. 23: 263–276. {{cite journal}}: Check date values in: |date= (help)
  57. ^ a b c Ellman, Michael (December 1975). "Did the Agricultural Surplus Provide the Resources for the Increase in Investment in the USSR During the First Five Year Plan?". The Economic Journal. 85: 844–863. doi:10.2307/2230627. JSTOR 2230627.
  58. ^ a b Stone, David R. (November 2005). "The First Five-Year Plan and the Geography of Soviet Defence Industry". Europe-Asia Studies. 57 (7): 1047–1063. doi:10.1080/09668130500302756. S2CID 153925109 – via Taylor & Francis, Ltd.
  59. ^ a b Bohlinger, Vincent (2013). "The development of sound technology in the Soviet film industry during the first Five-Year Plan". Studies in Russian & Soviet Cinema. 7 (2): 189–205. doi:10.1386/srsc.7.2.189_1. S2CID 159553067.