concept of article Petty's Place in the History of Economic Theory
Author | Charles Henry Hull |
---|---|
Language | English |
Subject | William Petty |
Publisher | The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 14, no. 3 |
Publication date | 1900 |
Pages | 307-340 |
OCLC | 5545673036 |
Text | Petty's Place in the History of Economic Theory at Wikisource |
Petty's Place in the History of Economic Theory is an academic article, written by Charles Henry Hull and published in The Quarterly Journal of Economics in 1900.
The article gives an overview of the life and work of William Petty, with a strong emphasis on the contribution of Petty to the development of early economic thinking. The article has reached some fame because Hull proposes in it the division of the writings of Petty into three chronological groups.
Bibliographical information
editHull, Charles Henry (1900). . The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 14: 307–340. doi:10.2307/1882563. ISSN 0033-5533. JSTOR 1882563. OCLC 5545673036 – via Wikisource.[1]
The text was reprinted in Blaug 1991.
Background
editThe contribution of William Petty to the early development of economic theory had already been a subject of research by different scholars. Hull mentions Zuckerkandl and von Bergmann in the introduction, and Ingram, Roscher, Kautz, McCulloch and Travers Twiss in the final chapter of 'Petty's Place in the History of Economic Theory'.[2]
Hull himself had published The Economic Writings of Sir William Petty (in 2 volumes), in 1899, in which he had already written a large 'Introduction', containing biographic information on Petty (and Graunt), and in which he spend quite some space on the debate concerning the authorship of the Observations upon the Bills of Mortality, concluding that Graunt was the author of it.
Nowadays, Hull's article is often mentioned in the same breath with Wilson Lloyd Bevan's Sir William Petty: A Study in english Economic Literature, published a few years earlier,[3] and demonstrating the revival of interest in Petty and his role in the development of (economic) thinking in the seventeenth century.[4]
Contents
editAfter a short introductory paragraph, 'Petty's place in the history of economic theory' holds 5 chapters.
The first chapter contains a short biography of Petty, and a general description of the economic writings, in which Hull makes a division in three (or four) groups, relating to distinct periods in Petty's life, and to books with "a common provocation and common characteristics":[5]
- the first group was written when Petty had returned to London after finishing his "Down Survey" in Ireland and consists mainly of A Treatise of Taxes & Contributions (written and first published 1662) and Verbum Sapienti (written 1665, printed 1691). Both texts relate to the discussions about fiscal issues, following the Restoration and the expenses in the first Dutch war.
- the second group contain The Political Anatomy of Ireland and Political Arithmetick. They were written some ten years later in Ireland. As Hull points out, the "direct impulse to their writing came from Dr. Edward Chamberlayne's Present State of England, published 1669".
- Again ten years later the group of pamphlets was written, that were contributions to the dispute whether London were a larger city than Paris, and that are titled the Essays in Political Arithmetick by Hull. This group of pamphlets has a close relation to John Graunt's Observations upon the Bills of Mortality of London.
- The Quantulumcunque concerning Money (written in 1682, and printed 1695, and perhaps in 1682), can probably be considered as belonging to a group of its own.
The division given here was still used by scholars at the end of the twentieth century.[6]
The second chapter describes the method and content of the economic writings of Petty. Perhaps this chapter is biased because of Hull's interest in the use of the statistical method in history and economics. He mentions Petty's method a statistical method, which is as such inapplicable to many subjects, and therefore restricting to some extent the content of the writings. Petty's predilection for a statistical method is due to the influence of Bacon. The well-known quote of Petty is "The Method I take is not very usual; for, instead of using only comparative and superlative Words, and intellectual Arguments, I have taken the course (as a Specimen of the Political Arithmetick I have long aimed at) to express myself in Terms of Number, Weight, or Measure; to use only Arguments of Sense, and to consider only such Causes, as have visible Foundations in Nature".[7]
But statistical sources were scarce in the 17th century. So a great number of basic facts, like the population of London, of England and of Ireland, had to be calculated, with all the risks of inaccuracies. And although he was aware of the fact that most of his calculations were mere guesses, he sometimes drew conclusions, that were far behind real. "He did not hesitate to advance, in all seriousness, the most astounding proposals for increasing the national wealth of the three kingdoms by a wholesale deportation of the Irish and Scotch into England,—proposals based solely upon the results of a complicated series of guesses and multiplications."[8]
Chapter three is devoted to the content of Petty's work. As far as his contributions to economic theory are concerned, Hull thinks, that the writings in the first group (and the Quantulumcunque) are most important. This brings the focus to the Treatise of Taxes & Contributions, and thus on taxation.[9]But out of the discussion of taxes also proceeds the treatment of rent.[10] Also Petty's theory of value "is developed incidentally to the discussion of taxation. It is an uncompromising quantity-of-labor theory.[11]
In the fourth chapter attention is first given to the second group of Petty's writings, the Political Anatomy of Ireland (1672) and the Political Arithmetick (1676). They are "predominantly descriptive" and economically, they add "little or nothing new to Petty's know ideas."[12] The Political Arithmetick, in contrast to the Political Anatomy, deals chiefly with England, and especially tries to prove that England is stronger and wealthier than France. To prove this, Petty uses clever calculations.
In this same chapter Hull treats the third group of Petty's writings, the Essays in Political Arithmetick, together with the Quantulumcunque. The Essays had a public purpose: to prove that London "was a greater city than Paris, and, indeed, the greatest in the world. (…) The present interest of the Essays lies chiefly in the light which they throw upon Petty's statistical method. Economically, they are barren. The Quantulumcunque, on the other hand, is full of meat."[13]
The final chapter tries to give a summary of the findings.
Reception
editThe division of the writings of Petty into three groups, which was proposed by Hull in this article, was still refered to at the end of the twentieth century, for instance by Hutchison in 1988[14] and by Yang in 1994.[15]
Footnotes
edit- ^ A transcription is also available in the Archive for the History of Economic Thought at McMaster University; see also this entry in EconPapers.
- ^ Most of the writers on the early development of economic thought are only mentioned in a few sentences. They are:
- Bergmann, Eugen von (1895) - Die Wirtschaftskrisen. Geschichte der nationalökonomischen Krisentheorieen. copy at the Internet Archive. There is only one place where Petty is mentioned: p. 235.
- Ingram, John Kells (1885) – 'Petty, Sir Willliam' in Encyclopædia Britannica, vol. XVIII, p. 724. See Chisholm, Hugh, ed. (1911). "Petty, Sir William". Encyclopædia Britannica (11th ed.). Cambridge University Press. (Hull (p. 339) mentions vol. XIX, p. 358).
- Kautz, Gyula (1860) - Die geschichtliche Entwickelung der National-Oekonomik und ihrer Literatur (Theorie und Geschichte der National-Oekonomik. Propyläen zum volks- und staatswirtschaftlichen Studium; vol. 2). Wien : Gerold. OCLC 64744129; also spelled as "Die geschichtliche Entwicklung...." (OCLC 603617578). Die geschichtliche Entwicklung der National-Oekonomik und ihrer Literatur at Google Books. Reprint 1970: Glashütten im Taunus : Auvermann, OCLC 74196935. See for instance p. 311f.. The paragraph is entitled "Die anti-merkantilistische Richtung und die Anfänge der wissenschaftlicheren Nationalökonomie in England" (p. 307-322) and comprises also Dudley North (1641-1691) and others.
- McCulloch, John Ramsay (1845) – The Literature of Political Economy. Hull mentions McCulloch only once in 'Petty's Place in the History of Economic Theory' (without mentioning a publication), but in his Economic Writings of 1899 (Hull (1899)), Hull does mention McCulloch on a few more place: on p. xxxix and p. l in regard to the relation of Petty and Graunt; on p. 257 on Political Arithmetick, ref Evelyn in "A select collection…."; on p. 639 = 638/9/40: bibl. [10e] on the reprint Quantulumcunque 1856 in "A select collection…." by McCulloch. In the list of books used (p. 668) he only mentions McCulloch 1845.
- Roscher, Wilhelm Georg Friedrich (1851) – Zur Geschichte der englischen Volkswirthschaftslehre im 16. und 17. Jahrhundert. In: Abhandlungen der k. sächs. Gesellschaft der Wissenschaften, Bd. 3. Leipzig. OCLC 741741146. copy at the Internet Archive; see ch. VII – 'Der politische Arithmetiker Petty', pp. 67-85 (mentioned by Hull on p. 339).
- Twiss, Travers (1847) - View of the Progress of Political Economy in Europe since the Sixteenth Century. London : Longman, Brown, Green, and Longmans. OCLC 1026140282. Copy at the Internet Archive, 2nd copy, 3rd copy, 4th copy.
- Zuckerkandl, Robert (1889) - Zur Theorie des Preises. OCLC 186012050, copy at the Internet Archive and 2nd copy, e.g. p. 12-15, 229-233. See also summary (in German).
Inglis Palgrave published the first edition of his Dictionary of Political Economy between 1894 and 1899. Edmond Fitzmaurice wrote an article on Petty in the third volume, p. 99-102. It is not mentioned by Hull. - ^ Bevan 1894.
- ^ See for instance McCormick 2009, p. 1 and Roncaglia 1985, p. 17.
- ^ Hull 1900, p. 311f.
- ^ One may wonder why Hull does not mention A Treatise of Ireland in this list. He was the first to have this manuscript, dated 1687, printed. (Hull 1899, p. 545-621).
- ^ Hull 1900, p. 314/5 see also: Petty' s Political Arithmetick (Preface) in Hull 1899 The Economic Writings of Sir William Petty vol. 1, p. 244. The quote dates back to 1672-6.
- ^ Hull 1900, p. 318.
- ^ Hull 1900, p. 322-325.
- ^ Hull 1900, p. 325-330.
- ^ Hull 1900, p. 330 Hull's peremptory statement is in contrast with for instance Kühnis 1960, who did extensive research of the value and price theoretical concepts of Petty and the "dogmenhistorische" background. Kühnis does not mention Hull's essay.
- ^ Hull 1900, p. 332.
- ^ Hull 1900, p. 337.
- ^ Hutchison 1988, p. 29.
- ^ Yang 1994, p. 62 (footnote 6).
Bibliography
edit- —— (1894). OCLC 615596640 – via Wikisource. . Publication of the American Economic Association. IX (4): 1–102.
- Blaug, Mark, ed. (1991). Pre-Classical Economists; Volume 1. Aldershot: Edward Elgar Publishing. ISBN 978-1-85278-468-3. OCLC 991657150.
- Hull, Charles Henry, ed. (1899). . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. OL 4007495W. OCLC 803827975 – via Wikisource.
- Hutchison, Terence (1988). Before Adam Smith : The Emergence of Political Economy, 1662-1776. Oxford / New York: Basil Blackwell. ISBN 0-631-15898-7.
- Kühnis, Sylva (1960). Die wert- und preistheoretischen Ideen William Pettys (in German). Winterthur: Verlag P.G. Keller. OCLC 244978509.
- McCormick, Ted (2009). William Petty And the Ambitions of Political Arithmetic. Oxford etc.: Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-954789-0. OCLC 361888129. (Google Books)
- Roncaglia, Alessandro (1985). Petty. The Origins of Political Economy. Translated by Isabella Cherubini. Cardiff etc: University College Cardiff Press. ISBN 0-906449-91-X. (translation of Petty: la nascita dell' economia politica,1977)
- Yang, Hong-Seok (1994). The Political Economy of Trade and Growth: An Analytical Interpretation of Sir James Steuart's Inquiry. Edward Elgar. ISBN 9781782543619. (especially section 'Petty's Natural Price', p. 61 - 68)