Proportional representation

Proportional representation (PR) refers to any type of electoral system under which subgroups of an electorate are reflected proportionately in the elected body.[1] The concept applies mainly to political divisions (political parties) among voters. The essence of such systems is that all votes cast – or almost all votes cast – contribute to the result and are effectively used to help elect someone. Under other election systems, a bare plurality or a scant majority are all that are used to elect candidates. PR systems provide balanced representation to different factions, reflecting how votes are cast.

Proportional representation means that each representative in an assembly is elected by a roughly equal number of voters. In the common case of electoral systems that only allow a choice of parties, the seats are allocated to parties in proportion to the vote tally or vote share each party receives.

Due to various factors, perfect proportionality is rarely achieved under PR systems. Optional rules applied in some PR systems may affect proportionality. Sometimes that effect is intended such as to suppress representation of small, extreme parties. The use of electoral thresholds (in list PR or MMP), small districts with few seats in each (in STV or list PR), or the absence or insufficient number of leveling seats (in list PR, MMP or AMS) may produce disproportionality. Other sources of disproportionality are electoral tactics, such as party splitting in some MMP systems.

Nonetheless, PR systems approximate proportionality much better than other systems[2] and are more resistant to gerrymandering and other forms of manipulation.

Proportional representation versus "representation by population"

edit

The term proportional representation may be used to mean fair representation by population as applied to states, regions, etc. However, representation being proportional with respect solely to population size is not considered to make an electoral system "proportional" the way the term is usually used.

For example, the US House of Representatives has 435 members, who each represent a roughly equal number of people; each state is allocated a number of members in accordance with its population size (aside from a minimum single seat that even the smallest state receives), thus producing equal representation by population. But members of the House are elected in single-member districts generally through first-past-the-post elections: a single-winner contest does not produce proportional representation as it has only one winner.

Conversely, the representation achieved under PR electoral systems is typically proportional to a district's population size (seats per set amount of population), votes cast (votes per winner), and party vote share (in party-based systems such as party-list PR). (Party-proportionality is also evident in many P.R. systems where party labels are used.)

The European Parliament gives each member state a number of seats roughly based on its population size (see degressive proportionality) and in each member state, the election must also be held using a PR system (with proportional results based on vote share). The members are elected through list P.R., STV or a system that allows votes to mark preferences for party lists. As well, country-wide electoral thresholds are restricted to five percent or lower, and to two to five percent in any district (or at-large district) where 35 or more are elected through list PR.[3]

Categories of proportional representation

edit

The most widely used families of PR electoral systems are party-list PR, used in 85 countries;[4] mixed-member PR (MMP), used in 7 countries;[5] and the single transferable vote (STV), used in Ireland,[6] Malta, the Australian Senate, and Indian Rajya Sabha.[7][8]

Proportional representation systems are used at all levels of government and are also used for elections to non-governmental bodies, such as corporate boards. Some P.R. systems do not necessitate the use of parties; others do. An outlier is Uruguay's party-list system where voters do not vote for parties but instead vote for candidates, and candidate totals are combined to compose party vote totals.

Districting under proportional representation

edit

All PR systems require multi-member election contests, meaning votes are pooled to elect multiple representatives at once. Pooling at the national level may be done in multi-member voting districts (in STV and most list-PR systems) or in single countrywide – a so called at-large – district (in only a few list-PR systems). A country-wide pooling of votes to elect more than a hundred members is used in Angola, for example.

Where PR is desired at the municipal level, a city-wide at-large districting is sometimes used, to allow as large a district magnitude as possible. In other cases, multi-member wards are used.

For large districts, party-list PR is often used, but even when list PR is used, districts sometimes contain fewer than 20 members.[9]

STV, a candidate-based PR system, has only rarely been used to elect more than 21 in a single contest.[a]

Some PR systems use party lists and at-large pooling or regional pooling in conjunction with single-member districts (such as New Zealand's MMP and Scotland's additional member system). Other PR systems use party lists and at-large pooling in conjunction with multi-member districts (Scandinavian countries). In these systems, votes are pooled to allocate leveling seats (top-up) to compensate for the disproportional results produced in single-member districts using FPTP or to increase the fairness already produced in multi-member districts using list PR. PR systems that achieve the highest levels of proportionality tend to use as general pooling as possible (typically country-wide) or districts with large numbers of seats (high district magnitude).

Basics

edit

Proportional representation refers to the general principle found in any electoral system in which the popularly chosen subgroups (parties) of an electorate are reflected proportionately in the elected body.[1] To achieve that intended effect, proportional electoral systems need to either have more than one seat in each district (e.g. single transferable vote), or have some form of compensatory seats (e.g. mixed-member proportional representation apportionment methods). A legislative body (e.g. assembly, parliament) may be elected proportionally, whereas there is no need for a single office (e.g. a president, or mayor) to be elected proportionately if no votes are for parties (subgroups).

In the European Parliament, for instance, each member state has a number of seats that is (roughly) proportional to its population, enabling geographical proportional representation. For these elections, all European Union (EU) countries also must use a proportional electoral system (enabling political proportional representation): When n% of the electorate support a particular political party or set of candidates as their favourite, then roughly n% of seats are allotted to that party or those candidates.[10] All PR systems aim to provide some form of equal representation for votes but may differ in their approaches on how they achieve this.

How party-list PR works

edit

Party-list PR is the most commonly used version of proportional representation. Voters cast votes for parties and each party is allocated seats based on its party share.

Some party-list PR systems use overall country-wide vote counts; others count vote shares in separate parts of the country and allocate seats in each part according to that specific vote count. Some use both.

List PR involves parties in the election process. Voters do not primarily vote for candidates (persons), but for electoral lists (or party lists), which are lists of candidates that parties put forward. The mechanism that allocates seats to the parties/lists is how these systems achieve proportionality. Once this is done, the candidates who take the seats are based on the order in which they appear on the list. This is the basic, closed list version of list PR.

An example election where the assembly has 200 seats to be filled is presented below. Every voter casts their vote for the list created by their favourite party and the results of the election are as follows (popular vote). Under party-list PR, every party gets a number of seats proportional to their share of the popular vote.

Party Popular vote Party-list PR – Sainte-Laguë method
Number of seats Seats %  
Party A 43.91% 88 44%
Party B 39.94% 80 40%
Party C 9.98% 20 10%
Party D 6.03% 12 6%
TOTAL 99.86% 200 100%

This is done by a proportional formula or method; for example, the Sainte-Laguë method – these are the same methods that may be used to allocate seats for geographic proportional representation (for example, how many seats each states gets in the US House of Representatives). Votes and seats often cannot be mathematically perfectly allocated, so some amount of rounding has to be done. The various methods deal with this in different ways, although the difference is reduced if there are many seats – for example, if the whole country is one district. Party-list PR is also more complicated in reality than in the example, as countries often use more than one district, multiple tiers (e.g. local, regional and national), open lists or an electoral threshold. This can mean that final seat allocations are frequently not proportional to the parties' vote share.

How the single transferable vote (STV) works

edit

The single transferable vote is an older method than party-list PR, and it does not need to formally involve parties in the election process. Instead of parties putting forward ordered lists of candidates from which winners are drawn in some order, candidates run by name, each voter casts one vote by marking preferences for candidates, with only one marked preference used to place the vote. Votes cast for the candidates determine the winners.

STV uses preferential ballots. The ranking is used to instruct election officials of how the vote should be transferred in case the first preference is marked for an un-electable candidate or for an already elected candidate. Each voter casts one vote and the district used elects multiple members (more than one, usually 3 to 7). Because parties play no role in the vote count, STV may be used for nonpartisan elections, such as the city council of Cambridge, Massachusetts.[11] A large proportion of the votes cast are used to actually elect someone so the result is mixed and balanced with no one voting block taking much more than its due share of the seats. Where party labels are indicated, proportionality party-wise is noticeable.

Counting votes under STV is more complicated than first-past-the-post voting, but the following example shows how the vote count is performed and how proportionality is achieved in a district with 3 seats. In reality, districts usually elect more members than that in order to achieve more proportional results. A risk is that if the number of seats is larger than, for example, 10 seats, the ballot will be so large as to be inconvenient and voters may find it difficult to rank the many candidates, although 21 are elected through STV in some elections with no great difficulty.[12] (In many STV systems, voters are not required to mark more choices than desired. Even if all voters marked only one preference, the resulting representation would be more balanced than under single-winner FPTP.)

Under STV, an amount that guarantees election is set, which is called the quota. In the example below, the Droop quota is used and any candidate who earns more than 25 percent of the vote is declared elected. Note that it is only possible for 3 candidates to each achieve that quota.

In the first count, the first preference (favourite candidate) marked on each of the ballots is counted. Candidates whose vote tally equals or passes the quota are declared elected as shown in the example below.

 
Simplified example of an STV ballot

The table below shows the initial count, or first round or stage, of the vote count process.

Quota is 25 percent plus 1. (Droop quota).

Jane Doe and Fred Rubble are elected in the first round.

Candidate Party Popular vote

(first preferences)

Elected? If elected: surplus votes
Jane Doe Party A 40% Yes 15%
Fred Rubble Party B 30% Yes 5%
Joe Smith Party A 16%
John Citizen Party A 11%
Mary Hill Party B 3%
TOTAL 100%

Next, surplus votes belonging to those already elected, votes the candidates received above the quota (votes that they did not need to be elected), are transferred to the next preference marked by the voters who voted for them. Continuing the example, suppose that all voters who marked first preference for Jane Doe marked John Citizen as their second choice. Based on this, Jane Doe's surplus votes are transferred to John Citizen. John Citizen achieves the quota and so is declared elected to the third and last seat that had to be filled.

Even if all of Fred Rubble's surplus had gone to Joe Smith, the vote transfer plus Smith's original votes would not add up to quota.

Party B did not have two quotas of votes so was not due two seats, while Party A with 67 percent of the vote, was. It is possible, in realistic STV elections, for a candidate to win without quota if they are still in the running when the field of candidates has thinned to the number of remaining open seats.

In this example, the district result is balanced party-wise. No one party took all the seats, as frequently happens under FPTP or other non-proportional voting systems. The result is fair – the most popular party took two seats; the less popular party took just one.

As well, the most popular candidates in each party won the party's seats. 81 percent of the voters saw their first choice elected. At least 15 percent of them (the Doe first, Citizen second voters) saw both their first and second choices elected – they were likely more than 15 percent if some "Citizen first" votes gave their second preference to Doe. Every voter had satisfaction of seeing someone of the party they support elected in the district.

Final-round vote tallies and party satisfaction break-down

(quota is 25 percent plus 1)

Candidate Party Current vote total Elected? Party First-preference votes

for candidates of party

Number of seats Party seats % under STV
Jane Doe Party A already elected (25%+1 vote) Yes Party A 67% 2 67%
John Citizen Party A 11% + 15% = 26% Yes
Joe Smith Party A 16%
Fred Rubble Party B already elected (30%)

(surplus votes not transferred)

Yes Party B 33% 1 33%
Mary Hill Party B 3%
TOTAL 100% 3 100% 3 100%

Under STV, to make up the 200-seat legislature as large as in the examples that follow, about 67 three-seat districts would be used. Districts with more seats would provide more proportional results – one form of STV in Australia uses a district with 21 members being elected at once. With a larger district magnitude, it is more likely that more than two parties will have some of their candidates elected.

With a lower district magnitude, it is more likely that only two parties will have their candidates elected. For example, in Malta, where STV is used with 5-member districts, it is common for successful candidates to receive 16.6 percent of the vote in the district. This produces a high effective threshold in the districts, and the country maintains a very strong two-party system.[13] However, about 4000 voters in a district would be enough to elect a third-party candidate if voters desired but this seldom happens.[13]

Conversely, New South Wales, which uses STV to elect its state legislative council in 21-seat contests, sees election of representatives of seven or eight different parties each time.[14] In this election about 1/22nd of the vote in the state is enough to take a seat, and seven or eight parties take at least that many votes, demonstrating a different voting pattern than Malta exhibits.

How mixed-member proportional representation (MMP) works

edit

Mixed-member proportional representation combines election of district members with election of additional members as compensatory top-up. Often MMP systems use single-member districts (SMDs) to elect district members. (Denmark, Iceland and Sweden use multi-member districts in their MMP systems.) MMP with SMDs is described here.

The mixed-member proportional system combines single member plurality voting (SMP), also known as first-past-the-post (FPTP), with party-list PR in a way that the overall result of the election is supposed to be proportional. The voter may vote for a district candidate as well as a party. The main idea behind MMP is compensation, meaning that the list-PR seat allocation is not independent of the results of the district level voting. First-past-the-post is a single winner system and cannot be proportional (winner-takes-all), so these disproportionalities are compensated by the party-list component.

A simple, yet common version of MMP has as many list-PR seats as there are single-member districts. In the example it can be seen, as is often the case in reality, that the results of the district elections are highly disproportional: large parties typically win more seats than they should proportionally, but there is also randomness – a party that receives more votes than another party might not win more seats than the other. Any such dis-proportionality produced by the district elections is addressed, where possible, by the allocation of the compensatory additional members.

     
 
Party Popular vote FPTP seats

(Number of districts won)

Compensatory seats under MMP

(party-list PR seats)

Total number of seats

under MMP

Seats % under MMP
Party A 43.91% 64 24 88 44%
Party B 39.94% 33 47 80 40%
Party C 9.98% 0 20 20 10%
Party D 6.03% 3 9 12 6%
TOTAL 100% 100 100 200 100%

MMP gives only as many compensatory seats to a party as they need to have the number of seats of each party be proportional. Another way to say this is that MMP focuses on making the outcome proportional.

Differences from mixed-member majoritarian system

edit

Compare the MMP example to a mixed-member majoritarian system, where the party-list PR seat allocation is independent of the district results (this is also called parallel voting). There is no compensation (no regard to how the district seats were filled) when allocating party-list seats so as to produce a proportional allocation of seats overall. The popular vote, the number of district seats won by each party, and the number of district and party-list PR seats are all the same as in the MMP example above, yet the parties' share of total seats is different.

Parallel voting (using non-compensatory party seats)

     
 
Party Popular vote FPTP seats

(Number of districts won)

Party-list PR seats

under parallel voting

Total number of seats

under parallel voting

Seats %

under parallel voting

Party A 43.91% 64 44 108 54.0%
Party B 39.94% 33 40 73 36.5%
Party C 9.98% 0 10 10 5.0%
Party D 6.03% 3 6 9 4.5%
TOTAL 100% 100 100 200 100%

The overall results are not proportional, although they are more balanced and fair than most single-winner first-past-the-post elections. Parallel voting is mostly semi-proportional. Mixed systems are the most proportional if the additional members are allocated in a compensatory way.

There are many versions of MMP in use. Some use only a single vote; in some, voters cast two votes, one for a local candidate and one for a party. Some allocate compensatory seats to best losers; others allocate according to party lists. Some use levelling seats to compensate for potential overhang seats; others don't. Most impose an electoral threshold in order for a party to be eligible for any additional seats; some allow parties that elect one or more district seats to be eligible for additional seats even if its party share is below the threshold. Any barrier to access to the additional seats may produce wasted votes and dis-proportionality in the final result.

As well, there is single non-transferable vote, which is also semi-proportional. It has the advantage that parties play no direct role in elections and voters do not need to mark ranked votes. Each voter casts one vote for a candidate and as many candidates win by plurality as the number of seats in the district. Due to each voter casting just one vote, as in STV, and each district electing multiple members, as in STV, mixed representation is produced in each district and overall rough proportionality more or less. Without transferable votes, more votes are wasted than under STV.

Advantages and disadvantages

edit

The case for a single transferable vote system, a form of proportional representation, was made by John Stuart Mill in his 1861 essay Considerations on Representative Government. His remarks are relevant to any form of PR.

In a representative body actually deliberating, the minority must of course be overruled; and in an equal democracy, the majority of the people, through their representatives, will outvote and prevail over the minority and their representatives. But does it follow that the minority should have no representatives at all? ... Is it necessary that the minority should not even be heard? Nothing but habit and old association can reconcile any reasonable being to the needless injustice. In a really equal democracy, every or any section would be represented, not disproportionately, but proportionately. A majority of the electors would always have a majority of the representatives, but a minority of the electors would always have a minority of the representatives. Man for man, they would be as fully represented as the majority. Unless they are, there is not equal government ... there is a part whose fair and equal share of influence in the representation is withheld from them, contrary to all just government, but, above all, contrary to the principle of democracy, which professes equality as its very root and foundation.[1]

Mill's essay does not support party-based proportional representation and may indicate a distaste for the ills of party-based systems in saying:

Of all modes in which a national representation can possibly be constituted, this one affords the best security for the intellectual qualifications desirable in the representatives. At present, by universal admission, it is becoming more and more difficult for any one who has only talents and character to gain admission into the House of Commons. The only persons who can get elected are those who possess local influence, or make their way by lavish expenditure, or who, on the invitation of three or four tradesmen or attorneys, are sent down by one of the two great parties from their London clubs, as men whose votes the party can depend on under all circumstances.[1]

Many political theorists agree with Mill[15] that in a representative democracy the representatives should represent all substantial segments of society but want reform rather than abolition of direct local community representation in the legislature.[16] (Mill himself only served one term as MP and then found it impossible to get a party to nominate him as their candidate. He was pointed out as an example of the kind of publicly spirited person who cannot even achieve a nomination under first-past-the-post.)[17]

STV and regionalized forms of additional-member systems or MMP systems (such as used to elect the Scottish Assembly) produce local area representation and overall PR through mixed, balanced representation at the district or regional level.[18][19]

Fairness

edit
 

PR tries to resolve the unfairness of single-winner and winner-take-all systems such as plurality voting, where the largest parties typically receive an "unfair" seat bonus and smaller parties are disadvantaged, always under-represented, and on occasion win no representation at all (Duverger's law).[20][21][22]: 6–7  Under FPTP, an established party in UK elections has been elected to majority government with as little as 33.7% of votes (in 2024,) and ten times on record since 1830, a government obtained the most seats while losing the popular vote to another party. In certain Canadian elections, majority governments have been formed by parties with the support of under 40 percent of votes cast (2011 Canadian election, 2015 Canadian election). If turnout levels in the electorate are less than 60 percent, such outcomes allow a party to form a majority government by convincing as few as one quarter of the electorate to vote for it.

That same situation can occur elsewhere as well. In the 2005 UK election, for example, the Labour Party under Tony Blair won a comfortable parliamentary majority with the votes of only 21.6 percent of the total electorate.[23]: 3  Such misrepresentation has been criticized as "no longer a question of 'fairness' but of elementary rights of citizens".[24]: 22 

However, some PR systems with a high electoral threshold, or other features that reduce proportionality, are not necessarily much fairer: in the 2002 Turkish general election, using an open-list list PR system with a 10 percent threshold, 46 percent of votes were wasted.[25]: 83  The other 54 percent of the votes did receive fair level of representation, though.

Under first-past-the-post, a third or so of members are elected with less than half the votes cast in their district, the majority of voters in such districts not getting any local representation and with no levelling seats being used, getting no representation entirely.

District-based winner-take-all systems also benefit regional parties by allowing them to win many seats in the region where they have a strong following even though they have less support nationally, while other parties with support that is not concentrated in a few districts, like various Green parties, win few or no seats. An example was Canada's 1993 election when the Bloc Québécois won 52 seats, all in Quebec, on 14 percent of the national vote , which was 12 more seats than it would have earned if seats were allocated based on the popular vote. The Progressive Conservatives collapsed to two seats on 16 percent of the votes spread nationally, when it was due 48. The Conservative party, although strong nationally, previously had won many of its seats in the West, In 1993, many of its Western supporters turned to the Reform party (a regional party), which won all its seats west of Ontario and most of its seats west of Saskatchewan.

The Conservative vote was spread so thin that in only one riding did it take a majority of votes, and in only two ridings did it take enough votes to win the seat. In about 150 districts the Conservative candidate received more than 15 percent of the vote, but in only two cases did the candidate take enough votes to win the seat. Under PR, the Conservative party's 16 percent of the votes would have been mirrored by elected repesentation (likely about 48 seats), while under FPTP the use of 295 separate election contests, with no overarching mechanism of proportionality, meant almost all of the Conservative votes were wasted.[22][26]

Similarly, in the 2015 UK General Election, conducted using single-winner FPTP, the Scottish National Party gained 56 seats, all in Scotland, with a 4.7 percent share of the national vote, while the UK Independence Party, with 12.6 percent, gained only a single seat.[27]

Representation of minor parties

edit

The use of multiple-member districts elects a greater variety of members compared to first past the post. It has been argued that in emerging democracies, inclusion of minorities in the legislature can be essential for social stability and to consolidate the democratic process.[25]: 58 

Critics of PR, on the other hand, claim inclusion can give extreme parties a foothold in parliament. That is sometimes cited as a cause for the collapse of the Weimar government. With very low thresholds, very small parties can act as "king-makers",[28] holding larger parties to ransom during coalition discussions. The example of Israel is often quoted,[25]: 59  These problems can be limited, as in the modern German Bundestag, by the use of a high electoral threshold, limiting the parties that receive parliamentary representation (This would in turn increase the number of wasted votes, if voters cannot register alternate preferences).

Another criticism is that the dominant parties in plurality/majoritarian systems, often looked on as "coalitions" or as "broad churches",[29] can fragment under PR as the election of candidates from smaller groups becomes possible. Israel, Brazil, and Italy (until 1993) are examples.[25]: 59, 89  However, research shows, in general, there is only a small increase in the number of parties in parliament (although small parties have larger representation) under PR.[30]

Open list systems and STV, the only prominent PR system that does not require political parties,[31] enable independent candidates to be elected. In Ireland, on average, about six independent candidates have been elected each parliament.[32] This can lead to a situation where forming a Parliamentary majority requires support of one or more of these independent representatives. In some cases these independents have positions that are closely aligned with the governing party and it hardly matters. The Irish Government formed after the 2016 election even included independent representatives in the cabinet of a minority government. In other cases, the independent member's electoral platform is entirely local and addressing this is a price for support.

Coalitions

edit

The election of smaller parties gives rise to one of the principal objections to PR systems, that they almost always result in coalition governments.[25]: 59 [15]

Supporters of PR see coalitions as an advantage, forcing compromise between parties to form a coalition at the centre of the political spectrum, and often when an election forces government change, some of the old coalition are in the new coalition so PR produces continuity and stability. Opponents counter that with many policies, compromise is not possible. Neither can many policies be easily positioned on the left-right spectrum (for example, the environment). So policies are horse-traded during coalition formation, with the consequence that voters have no way of knowing which policies will be pursued by the government they elect; voters have less influence on governments. Also, coalitions do not necessarily form at the centre, and small parties can have excessive influence, supplying a coalition with a majority only on condition that a policy or policies favoured by few voters is/are adopted. Most importantly, some say the ability of voters to vote an unpopular party out of power is curtailed.[15]

All these disadvantages, the PR opponents contend, are avoided by two-party plurality voting systems. Coalitions are rare; the two dominant parties necessarily compete at the centre for votes, so that governments are more reliably moderate; the strong opposition necessary for proper scrutiny of government is assured; and governments remain sensitive to public sentiment because they can be, and are, regularly voted out of power.[15] However, this is not necessarily so; a two-party system can result in a "drift to extremes", hollowing out the centre,[33] or, at least, in one party drifting to an extreme.[34] As well, a two-party election system may operate in an oligopolistic manner, with both parties ignoring a particular viewpoint (the two parties engaging in too much compromise), or one party may verge off, having been controlled by an extreme group, so creating polarization.[35] A two-party plurality election system means there are many safe seats, districts where only one party has a chance to be elected. This often leads to polarization and low voter turnout, and sometimes opens door to foreign interference at the nomination stage.[36]

The opponents of PR also contend that coalition governments created under PR are less stable, and elections are more frequent. Italy is an often-cited example with many governments composed of many different coalition partners. However, Italy is unusual in that both its houses can make a government fall, whereas other countries, including many PR nations, have either just one house or have one of their two houses be the core body supporting a government. Italy's current parallel voting system is not PR, so Italy is not an appropriate candidate for measuring the stability of PR.[citation needed] Canada, which uses FPTP with a multi-party system, had more elections between 1945 and 2017 than PR countries such as Norway, Germany and Ireland.[37]

Voter participation

edit

Plurality systems usually result in single-party-majority government because generally fewer parties are elected in large numbers under FPTP compared to PR, and FPTP compresses politics to little more than two-party contests. Relatively few votes in a few of the most finely balanced districts, the "swing seats", are able to swing majority control in the house. Incumbents in less evenly divided districts are invulnerable to slight swings of political mood. In the UK, for example, about half the constituencies have always elected the same party since 1945;[38] in the 2012 US House elections 45 districts (10% of all districts) were uncontested by one of the two dominant parties.[39] Voters who know their preferred candidate will not win have little incentive to vote, and even if they do their votes have no effect, although they are still counted in the popular vote calculation.[25]: 10 

With PR, there are no "swing seats". Most votes contribute to the election of a candidate, so parties need to campaign in all districts, not just those where their support is strongest or where they perceive most advantage. This fact in turn encourages parties to be more responsive to voters, producing a more "balanced" ticket by nominating more women and minority candidates.[22] On average about 8 percent more women are elected in PR systems than non-PR systems.[30]

Since most votes count, there are fewer "wasted votes", so voters, aware that their vote can make a difference, are more likely to make the effort to vote, and less likely to vote tactically. Compared to countries with plurality electoral systems, voter turnout improves and the population is more involved in the political process.[25][22][30] However, some experts argue that transitioning from plurality to PR only increases voter turnout in geographical areas associated with safe seats under the plurality system; turnout may decrease in areas formerly associated with swing seats.[40]

Proportional systems show higher political efficacy, citizens' trust in their ability to influence and understand the government, compared to plurality and majoritarian systems.[41]

Gerrymandering

edit

First-past-the-post elections are dependent on the drawing of boundaries of their single-member districts, a process vulnerable to political interference (gerrymandering) even if districts are drawn in such a way as to ensure approximately equal representation. However, because voter turnout varies from district to district and because in one district a winner might take 80 percent of the vote while in another the winner might be elected with only 30 percent of the vote, there might be wide variation in votes-per-winner, even if districts are drawn in such a way as to take in equivalent population. As one party might take its seats with a low votes-per-winner ratio while another party might not have that advantage, the result is likely to be disproportionate.[42]

To compound the problem, boundaries have to be periodically re-drawn to accommodate population changes. Even apolitically drawn boundaries can unintentionally produce the effect of gerrymandering, reflecting naturally occurring concentrations.[43]: 65 

PR systems, due to having larger districts with multiple members, are less prone to gerrymandering – research suggests five-seat districts or larger are immune to gerrymandering.[43]: 66 

Equality of size of multiple-member districts is not important (the number of seats can vary) so districts can be aligned with historical territories of varying sizes such as cities, counties, states or provinces. Later population changes can be accommodated by simply adjusting the number of representatives in the district, without having to re-draw a single boundary. For example, Mollison in his 2010 plan for STV for the UK divided the country into 143 districts and then allocated varying number of seats to each district (to add up to the existing total of 650 MPs) depending on the number of voters in each but with wide ranges (his five-seat districts include one with 327,000 voters and another with 382,000 voters). His district boundaries follow historical county and local authority boundaries, yet he achieves more uniform representation than does the Boundary Commission, the body responsible for balancing the UK's first-past-the-post constituency sizes.[38][44]

Mixed-member systems are susceptible to gerrymandering for the local seats that remain a part of such systems. Under parallel voting, a semi-proportional system, there is no compensation for the effects that such gerrymandering might have. Under MMP, the use of compensatory list seats makes gerrymandering less of an issue. However, its effectiveness in this regard depends upon the features of the system, including the size of the regional districts, the relative share of list seats in the total, and opportunities for collusion that might exist. A striking example of how the compensatory mechanism can be undermined can be seen in the 2014 Hungarian parliamentary election, where the leading party, Fidesz, combined gerrymandering and decoy lists, which resulted in a two-thirds parliamentary majority from a 45% vote.[45][46] This illustrates how certain implementations of mixed systems (if non-compensatory or insufficiently compensatory) can produce moderately proportional outcomes, similar to parallel voting.

edit

It is generally accepted that a particular advantage of plurality electoral systems such as first-past-the-post, or majoritarian electoral systems such as the alternative vote, is the geographic link between representatives and their constituents.[25]: 36 [47]: 65 [24]: 21  A notable disadvantage of PR is that, as its multiple-member districts are made larger, this link is weakened.[25]: 82  In party list PR systems without delineated districts, such as the Netherlands and Israel, the there is no geographic link between representatives and their constituents. This makes it more difficult for local or regional issues to be addressed at the federal level. With relatively small multiple-member districts, in particular with STV, there are counter-arguments: about 90 percent of voters can consult a representative they voted for, someone whom they might think more sympathetic to their problem. In such cases it is sometimes argued that constituents and representatives have a closer link;[38][43]: 212  constituents have a choice of representative so they can consult one with particular expertise in the topic at issue.[43]: 212 [48] With multiple-member districts, prominent candidates have more opportunity to be elected in their home constituencies, which they know and can represent authentically. There is less likely to be a strong incentive to parachute them into constituencies in which they are strangers and thus less than ideal representatives.[49]: 248–250  Mixed-member PR systems incorporate single-member districts to preserve the link between constituents and representatives.[25]: 95  However, because up to half the parliamentary seats are list rather than district seats, the districts are necessarily up to twice as large as with a plurality/majoritarian system where all representatives serve single-member districts.[24]: 32 

An interesting case occurred in the Netherlands, when "out of the blue" a party for the elderly, the General Elderly Alliance gained six seats in the 1994 election. The other parties had not paid attention, but this made them aware. With the next election, the Party of the Elderly was gone, because the established parties had started to listen to the elderly. Today, a party for older citizens, 50PLUS, has established itself in the Netherlands, albeit never winning as many as six seats.

This can be seen as an example how geographic representation is not all-important and does not overshadow all other particulars of the voting population. Voting in a single-member district restricts the voters to a specific geography where their votes either go to the winner in the district or are wasted. MMP allows a vote (in the form of the voter's party vote) to be used outside the district if necessary to produce representation for the voter.[50]

Potential lack of balance in presidential systems

edit

In a presidential system, the president is chosen independently from the parliament. As a consequence, it is possible to have a divided government where a parliament and president have opposing views and may want to balance each other's influence. However, the proportional system favors government of coalitions of many smaller parties that require compromising and negotiating topics.[citation needed] As a consequence, these coalitions might have difficulties presenting a united front to counter presidential influence, leading to a lack of balance between these two powers. With a proportionally elected House, a President may strong-arm certain political issues[citation needed]

This issue does not happen in a parliamentary system, where the prime-minister is elected indirectly by the parliament itself. As a consequence, a divided government is impossible. Even if the political views change with time and the prime minister loses their support from parliament, they can be replaced with a motion of no confidence. Effectively, both measures make it impossible to create a divided government.

Attributes of PR systems

edit

District magnitude

edit

Academics agree that the most important influence on proportionality is an electoral district's magnitude, the number of representatives elected from the district. As magnitude increases, proportionality improves.[25]

At one extreme, where the district encompasses the entire country (and with a low minimum threshold, highly proportionate representation of political parties can result), parties gain by broadening their appeal by nominating more minority and women candidates.[25]: 83  Very few countries elect using an at-large district – only the Netherlands, Israel, and a few others. Almost all PR systems use multi-member districts that divide the electorate while producing local representation. At the other extreme, the binomial electoral system used in Chile between 1989 and 2013,[51] a nominally proportional open-list system, featured two-member districts. This system allowed a party winning more than a quarter of the vote in a district to be ignored and gave just one seat to a party with 5 percent of the vote, so it is generally not considered a genuinely proportional system.[25]: 79 

Similar plans for very small districts that produce quasi- or semi-proportional representation have been proposed in the United States and United Kingdom. The FairVote plan for STV in the US House of Representatives proposes three- to five-member districts, so a party with around one-fourth of the vote in a district would win a seat there and in most districts no one party would take all the seats.[52] In Mollison's plan for STV in the UK, four- and five-member districts are mostly used, with three and six seat districts used as necessary to fit existing boundaries, and even two and single member districts used where geography dictates.[38]

After the introduction of STV in Ireland in 1921, district magnitudes slowly diminished as more and more three-member constituencies were defined, benefiting the dominant Fianna Fáil party, until 1979, when an independent boundary commission was established, reversing the trend.[53] In 2010, a parliamentary constitutional committee recommended a minimum magnitude of four.[54]

Electoral threshold

edit

The electoral threshold is the minimum vote required to win one seat. The lower the threshold, the higher the proportion of votes contributing to the election of representatives and the lower the proportion of votes wasted.[25] An explicit threshold requires parties to win a certain percentage of the vote in order to be awarded seats from the party lists, and otherwise denies any representation to parties . By contrast, a natural threshold is (equal to a Droop quota) is the smallest number of votes needed to mathematically guarantee a seat.[25]: 83 

In New Zealand, which uses mixed-member proportional representation, the electoral threshold is 5% of the national vote but parties that win at least one constituency seat get their due number of seats even if they do not achieve the threshold.[55]

Turkey sets its electoral threshold at 7 percent,[56] while the Netherlands sets its threshold at a single Hare quota, or 0.67 percent of national vote count.[25]

Israel has raised its threshold from 1 percent (before 1992) to 1.5 percent (1992-2004), to 2 percent (in 2006, and to 3.25 percent in 2014. Because that country uses at-large districting, the natural threshold would be less than 1 percent, much lower than the electoral threshold.[57]

South Africa has no explicit electoral threshold.[citation needed]

In STV elections, a candidate winning an electoral quota's worth of votes (usually Droop quota) is assured election, and thus that candidate's party would win one seat in the district.[58]

Party magnitude

edit

Party magnitude is the number of candidates elected from one party in one district. As district magnitude increases, it is likely more parties will elect larger delegations in the district and thus enjoy larger party magnitude.[59]

As party magnitude increases, a party may decide to broaden its appeal by nominating women and members of minority groups.[59] A balanced ticket will be more successful than a narrow slate. This encourages parties to nominate women and minority candidates.[60]

But under STV, nominating too many candidates can be counter-productive, splitting the first-preference votes and allowing candidates to be eliminated before receiving transferred votes from elected or eliminated candidates of the same party and of other parties. An example of this was identified in a ward in the 2007 Scottish local elections where Labour, putting up three candidates, won only one seat while they might have won two if they had only run two and party support (as seen in first-preference votes) had been redistributed among just the two.[38]

The same effect may have contributed to the collapse of representation of Fianna Fáil in the 2011 Irish general election.[61] The party received about half the votes compared to the previous election but received only one quarter of the seats it had received in that earlier election. In Dublin West, for example, it ran 13 candidates but elected just one.[62]

But generally in STV contests, transfers of votes allow each party to take roughly its due share of the seats based on vote tallies of the party's candidates. As well, where all the candidates of a party preferred by a voter are eliminated, the vote may find usefulness by being transferred to a candidate of a different party who is liked by the voter.[63]

Others

edit

Other aspects of PR can influence proportionality such as the size of the elected body, the choice of open or closed lists, ballot design, and vote counting methods.

Measuring disproportionality

edit

Exact proportionality has a single unambiguous definition: the seat shares must exactly equal the vote shares, measured as seats-to-votes ratio. When this condition is violated, the allocation is disproportional, and it may be interesting to examine the degree of disproportionality – the degree to which the number of seats won by each party differs from that of a perfectly proportional outcome. This degree does not have a single unambiguous definition. Some common disproportionality indexes are:[64]

  • The Gallagher Index – involves squaring the difference between each party's vote share and seat share, and finding the square root of half of the sum of these amounts.
  • Wasted vote, which counts votes cast for parties that did not obtain any seats (or votes not used to elect anyone at the district level, in systems where district-level electing is all that is used)
  • The Sainte-Laguë Index – where the squared discrepancy from ideal seats-to-votes ratio is weighted equally for each voter.

Disproportionality changes from one election to another depending on voter behavior and size of electoral threshold or natural threshold. This is seen in the number of wasted votes in New Zealand.[65] In 2005 New Zealand general election every party receiving more than 1 percent of the votes acquired seats due to every party at that level getting at least one seat in first-past-the-post voting. This election thus saw far fewer wasted votes compared to other elections when only the most popular parties took district seats.

Different indexes measure different concepts of disproportionality. Some disproportionality concepts have been mapped to social welfare functions.[66]

Disproportionality indexes are sometimes used to evaluate existing and proposed electoral systems. For example, the Canadian Parliament's 2016 Special Committee on Electoral Reform recommended that if the existing election system was replaced, the new system should be designed to achieve "a Gallagher score of 5 or less". This low level of disproportionality is consistently achieved in European PR[67] but is much lower than was produced in the 2015 Canadian election under first-past-the-post voting, where the Gallagher index was 12.[68]

PR electoral systems

edit

Party-based systems

edit

Party list PR

edit

Party list proportional representation is an electoral system in which seats are first allocated to parties based on vote share, and then assigned to party-affiliated candidates on the parties' electoral lists. This system is used in many countries, including Finland (open list), Latvia (open list), Sweden (open list), Israel (national closed list), Brazil (open list), Kazakhstan (closed list), Nepal (closed list) as adopted in 2008 in first CA election, the Netherlands (open list), Russia (closed list), South Africa (closed list), Democratic Republic of the Congo (open list), and Ukraine (open list). For elections to the European Parliament, most member states use open lists; but most large EU countries use closed lists, so that the majority of EP seats are distributed by those.[69] Local lists were used to elect the Italian Senate during the second half of the 20th century. Some common types of electoral lists are:

  • Closed list systems, where each party lists its candidates according to the party's candidate selection process. This sets the order of candidates on the list and thus, in effect, their probability of being elected. The first candidate on a list, for example, will get the first seat that party wins. Each voter casts a vote for a list of candidates. Voters, therefore, do not have the option to express their preferences at the ballot as to which of a party's candidates are elected into office.[70][71] A party is allocated seats in proportion to the number of votes it receives.[72]
  • Ley de Lemas, an intermediate system used in Uruguay, where each party presents several closed lists, each representing a faction. Seats are distributed between parties according to the number of votes, and then between the factions within each party.[citation needed]
  • Open list systems, where voters may vote, depending on the model, for one person, or for two or more, or vote for a party list but indicate their order of preference within the list. These votes sometimes rearrange the order of names on the party's list and thus which of its candidates are elected. Nevertheless, the number of candidates elected from each list is determined by the number of votes that the list receives or that the candidates on the list receive.[73]
  • Localized list systems, where parties divide their candidates in single member-like constituencies, which are ranked inside each general party list depending by their percentages. This method allows electors to judge every single candidate as in a FPTP system.
  • Two-tier party list systems, as in Denmark, Norway, and Sweden. These operate similarly to mixed-member proportional systems or additional member systems. For example, Denmark is divided into ten multiple-member voting districts arranged in three regions, electing 135 representatives. In addition, 40 compensatory seats are elected. Voters have one vote. It is cast for an individual candidate or for a party list on the district ballot. To determine district winners, parties are allocated district seats based on their district vote shares. Candidates in the district are apportioned their share of their party's district list vote plus their individual votes, and the most-popular are elected to fill their party's seats. Compensatory seats are apportioned to the regions according to the party votes aggregated nationally, and then to the districts where the compensatory representatives are determined. In the 2007 general election, the district magnitudes, including compensatory representatives, varied between 14 and 28. The basic design of the system has remained unchanged since its introduction in 1920.[74][75][76]

Mixed systems

edit

There are mixed electoral systems combining a plurality/majority formula with a proportional formula[77] or using the proportional component to compensate for disproportionality caused by the plurality/majority component.[78][79]

The most prominent mixed compensatory system is mixed-member proportional representation (MMP). It combines a single-district vote, usually first-past-the-post, with a compensatory regional or nationwide party list proportional vote. For example, suppose that a party wins 10 seats based on plurality, but requires 15 seats in total to obtain its proportional share of an elected body. A fully proportional mixed compensatory system would award this party 5 compensatory (PR) seats, raising the party's seat count from 10 to 15. MMP has the potential to produce proportional or moderately proportional election outcomes, depending on a number of factors such as the ratio of FPTP seats to PR seats, the existence or nonexistence of extra compensatory seats to make up for overhang seats, and electoral thresholds.[80][81][82] It was invented for the German Bundestag after the Second World War, and has spread to Lesotho, Bolivia, New Zealand and Thailand. The system is also used for the Scottish Parliament where it is called the additional member system.[83][5]

Voters typically have two votes, one for their district representative and one for the party list. The list vote usually determines how many seats are allocated to each party in parliament. After the district winners have been determined, sufficient candidates from each party list are elected to "top-up" each party to the overall number of parliamentary seats due to it according to the party's overall list vote. Before apportioning list seats, all list votes for parties which failed to reach the threshold are discarded. If eliminated parties lose seats in this manner, then the seat counts for parties that achieved the threshold improve. Any direct seats won by independent candidates are subtracted from the parliamentary total used to apportion list seats.[84]

Proportionality of MMP can be compromised if the ratio of list to district seats is too low, as it may then not be possible to completely compensate district seat disproportionality.

Another factor can be how overhang seats are handled, district seats that a party wins in excess of the number due to it under the list vote. To achieve proportionality, other parties require "balance seats", increasing the size of parliament by twice the number of overhang seats, but this is not always done. Until recently, Germany increased the size of parliament by the number of overhang seats but did not use the increased size for apportioning list seats. This was changed for the 2013 national election after the constitutional court rejected the previous law, not compensating for overhang seats had resulted in a negative vote weight effect.[85] Lesotho, Scotland and Wales do not increase the size of parliament at all, even if there are overhang seats. In 2012, a New Zealand parliamentary commission proposed abandoning compensation for overhang seats, and so fixing the size of parliament. At the same time, it proposed abolishing the single-seat threshold (the go-around past the electoral threshold used by some small parties to get their due share of seats). It was expected that such seats would be overhang seats. If that was done without abolishing overhang compensation, it would have increased the size of parliament further through the overhang compensation. The commission also proposed reducing the electoral threshold from 5 percent to 4 percent. It was expected that proportionality would not suffer from these changes.[25][86]

Similarly to MMP, mixed single vote systems (MSV) use a proportional formula for allocating seats on the compensatory tier, but voters only have one vote that functions on both levels. MSV may use a positive vote transfer system, where unused votes are transferred from the lower tier to the upper, compensatory tier, where only these are used in the proportional formula. Alternatively, the MMP (seat linkage) algorithm can be used with a mixed single vote to "top-up" to a proportional result. With MSV, the similar requirements as in MMP apply to guarantee an overall proportional result.

Parallel voting (MMM) systems use proportional formulas to allocate seats on a proportional tier separately from other tiers. Certain systems, like scorporo use a proportional formula after combining results of a parallel list vote with transferred votes from lower tiers (using negative or positive vote transfer).

Another mixed system is dual-member proportional representation (DMP). It is a single-vote system that elects two representatives in every district.[87] The first seat in each district is awarded to the candidate who wins a plurality of the votes, similar to FPTP voting. The remaining seats are awarded in a compensatory manner to achieve proportionality across a larger region. DMP employs a formula similar to the "best near-winner" variant of MMP used in the German state of Baden-Württemberg.[88] In Baden-Württemberg, compensatory seats are awarded to candidates who receive high levels of support at the district level compared with other candidates of the same party. DMP differs in that at most one candidate per district is permitted to obtain a compensatory seat. If multiple candidates contesting the same district are slated to receive one of their parties' compensatory seats, the candidate with the highest vote share is elected and the others are eliminated. DMP is similar to STV in that all elected representatives, including those who receive compensatory seats, serve their local districts. Invented in 2013 in the Canadian province of Alberta, DMP received attention on Prince Edward Island where it appeared on a 2016 plebiscite as a potential replacement for FPTP,[89] but was eliminated on the third round.[90][91] It was also one of three proportional voting system options on a 2018 referendum in British Columbia.[92][93][94]

Biproportional apportionment

edit

Biproportional apportionment aims to achieve proportionality in two dimensions, for example: proportionality by region and proportionality by party. There are several mathematical methods to attain biproportionality.

One method is called iterative proportional fitting (IPF). It was proposed for elections by the mathematician Michel Balinski in 1989, and first used by the city of Zürich for its council elections in February 2006, in a modified form called "new Zürich apportionment" (Neue Zürcher Zuteilungsverfahren). Zürich had had to modify its party list PR system after the Swiss Federal Court ruled that its smallest wards, as a result of population changes over many years, unconstitutionally disadvantaged smaller political parties. With biproportional apportionment, the use of open party lists has not changed, but the way winning candidates are determined has. The proportion of seats due to each party is calculated according to their overall citywide vote, and then the district winners are adjusted to conform to these proportions. This means that some candidates, who would otherwise have been successful, can be denied seats in favor of initially unsuccessful candidates, in order to improve the relative proportions of their respective parties overall. This peculiarity is accepted by the Zürich electorate because the resulting city council is proportional and all votes, regardless of district magnitude, now have equal weight. The system has since been adopted by other Swiss cities and cantons.[95][96]

Balinski has proposed another variant called fair majority voting (FMV) to replace single-winner plurality/majoritarian electoral systems, in particular the system used for the US House of Representatives. FMV introduces proportionality without changing the method of voting, the number of seats, or the – possibly gerrymandered – district boundaries. Seats would be apportioned to parties in a proportional manner at the state level.[96] In a related proposal for the UK parliament, whose elections are contested by many more parties, the authors note that parameters can be tuned to adopt any degree of proportionality deemed acceptable to the electorate. In order to elect smaller parties, a number of constituencies would be awarded to candidates placed fourth or even fifth in the constituency – unlikely to be acceptable to the electorate, the authors concede – but this effect could be substantially reduced by incorporating a third, regional, apportionment tier, or by specifying minimum thresholds.[97]

Candidate-based systems

edit

Single transferable vote

edit

The single transferable vote (STV), also called ranked choice voting,[98][11] is a ranked system: voters rank candidates in order of preference. Voting districts usually elect three to seven representatives; each voter casts just one vote. The count is cyclic, electing or eliminating candidates and transferring votes until all seats are filled. A candidate whose tally reaches a quota, the minimum vote that guarantees election, is declared elected. The candidate's surplus votes (those in excess of the quota) are transferred to other candidates at a fraction of their value proportionate to the surplus, according to the voters' preferences. If there are no surplus votes to transfer and there are still seats to fill, the least popular candidate is eliminated, those votes being transferred to their next preference at full value. The votes are transferred according to the next marked preference. Any votes that cannot be transferred are moved to a pile labelled exhausted or non-transferable.

The count continues until all the seats are filled or until there is only one more candidate than the number of remaining open seats. At that point all of them except the least popular candidate are declared elected, even if they do not have quota.

The transfer of votes of eliminated candidates is simple – the transfer of surplus votes is more involved. There are various methods for transferring surplus votes.

Manual methods used in early times and still today in places where STV was adopted in early 20th century (Ireland and Malta) transfer surplus votes according to a randomly selected sample, or transfer only a segment of the votes held by the successful candidate as surplus, selected based on the next usable marked preference.

Other more recent methods transfer all votes held by successful candidate at a fraction of their value (the fraction derived by the surplus divided by the candidate's tally) and with reference to all the marked preferences on the ballots, not just the next usable preference. They may need the use of a computer.

The different methods may not produce the same result in all respects. But the front runners in the first count before any transfers are conducted are all or mostly elected in the end under any STV variant, so the various methods of transfers all produce much the same result.

Some variants of STV allow transfers to already elected or eliminated candidates, and these, too, can require a computer.[99][100]

In effect, the method produces groups of voters of much the same size so the overall effect is to reflect the diversity of the electorate, each substantial group electing one or more representatives that the group had voted for.

In Cambridge, under STV, 90 percent of voters see their vote help to elect a candidate, more than 65 percent of voters see their first choice candidate elected, and more than 95 percent of voters see one of their top three choices win.[101]

Other reports claim that 90 percent of voters have a representative to whom they gave their first preference. Voters can choose candidates using any criteria they wish, the proportionality is implicit.[38] Another source states that, when STV was used between 1925 and 1955 in Cincinnati, 90 percent of voters saw their first choice elected or their vote used to elect a secondary preference, with about 60 to 74 percent of voters seeing their first choice elected, even if their vote was not used to elect that person because it was transferred on as a surplus vote.[102]

Political parties are not necessary; all other prominent PR electoral systems presume that parties reflect voters wishes, which many believe gives power to parties.[99] STV satisfies the electoral system criterion proportionality for solid coalitions – a solid coalition for a set of candidates is the group of voters that rank all those candidates above all others – and is therefore considered a system of proportional representation.[99]

However, the small district magnitude used in STV elections (usually 5 to 9 seats, but sometimes rising to 21) has been criticized as impairing proportionality, especially when more parties compete than there are seats available,[15]: 50  and STV has, for this reason, sometimes been labelled "quasi proportional".[103]: 83 

While this may be true when considering districts in isolation, results overall are usually more proportional.

Even though Ireland has particularly small magnitudes (3 to 5 seats), results of STV elections are "highly proportional".[25]: 73 [6] In 1997, the average magnitude was 4. Eight parties gained representation, four of them with less than 3% of first-preference votes nationally. Six independent candidates also won election.[53]

There have been claims made that STV handicaps certain extreme candidates because, to gain transfers based on back-up preferences and so improve their chance of election, candidates need to canvass voters beyond their own circle of supporters, and so need to moderate their views.[104] This argument is made from the high natural threshold STV provides with low district magnitude.[105]

Conversely, widely respected candidates can win election even if they receive relatively few first preferences. They do this by benefiting from strong subordinate preference support. Of course, they must have enough initial support so that they are not in the bottom rung of popularity or they will be eliminated when the field of candidate is thinned.[38]

Charles Dodgson (Lewis Carroll), the polymath logician and author, developed a passionate interest [106] in voting methods. He believed RCV/STV to be fundamentally flawed, particularly regarding the allocation of “surplus” votes. His novel solution was to let the candidates themselves caucus and “club” votes together through the process of a negotiated consensus.[107] As he stated:[108]

May I, in conclusion, point out that the method advocated in my pamphlet (where each elector names one candidate only, and the candidates themselves can, after the numbers are announced, club their votes, so as to bring in others besides those already announced as returned) would be at once perfectly simple and perfectly equitable in its result?

However, his entreaties to Lord Salisbury, leader of the Conservative Party and future prime minister, to adopt “clubbing” were rejected in 1884 [109] as “too sweeping a change". Subsequently, he joined with Thomas Hare and several Conservative and Liberal members of Parliament to found the Proportional Representation Society (later the Electoral Reform Society) and to pursue STV.

Proportional approval voting

edit

Systems can be devised that aim at proportional representation but are based on approval votes on individual candidates (not parties). Such is the idea of proportional approval voting (PAV). It satisifes an adaptation of PR called extended justified representation (EJR).[110]

When there are many seats to be filled, as in a legislature, counting ballots under PAV may not be feasible, so sequential variants have been used, such as sequential proportional approval voting (SPAV). SPAV was used briefly in Sweden during the early 1900s.[111] The vote counting procedure occurs in rounds. The first round of SPAV is identical to approval voting. All ballots are added with equal weight, and the candidate with the highest overall score is elected. In all subsequent rounds, ballots that support candidates who have already been elected are added with a reduced weight. Thus, voters who support none of the winners in the early rounds are increasingly likely to elect one of their preferred candidates in a later round. The procedure has been shown to yield proportional outcomes especially when voters are loyal to distinct groups of candidates (e.g. political parties).[112][113]

Reweighted range voting (RRV) uses the same method as sequential proportional approval voting but uses a score ballot.[citation needed] Reweighted range voting was used for the nominations in the Visual Effects category for recent Academy Award Oscars from 2013 through 2017,[114][115] and is used in the city of Berkeley, California, for sorting the priorities of the city council.[116]

History

edit

Pre–19th century

edit

One of the earliest proposals of proportionality in an assembly was by John Adams in his influential pamphlet Thoughts on Government, written in 1776 during the American Revolution:

It should be in miniature, an exact portrait of the people at large. It should think, feel, reason, and act like them. That it may be the interest of this Assembly to do strict justice at all times, it should be an equal representation, or in other words equal interest among the people should have equal interest in it.[117]

Mirabeau, speaking to the Assembly of Provence on 30 January 1789, was also an early proponent of a proportionally representative assembly:[118]

A representative body is to the nation what a chart is for the physical configuration of its soil: in all its parts, and as a whole, the representative body should at all times present a reduced picture of the people, their opinions, aspirations, and wishes, and that presentation should bear the relative proportion to the original precisely.

In February 1793, the Marquis de Condorcet led the drafting of the Girondist constitution which proposed a limited voting scheme with proportional aspects. Before that could be voted on, the Montagnards took over the National Convention and produced their own constitution. On 24 June, Saint-Just proposed the single non-transferable vote, which is semi-proportional, for national elections but the constitution was passed on the same day specifying first-past-the-post voting.[118]

Already in 1787, James Wilson, like Adams a US Founding Father, understood the importance of multiple-member districts: "Bad elections proceed from the smallness of the districts which give an opportunity to bad men to intrigue themselves into office",[119] and again, in 1791, in his Lectures on Law: "It may, I believe, be assumed as a general maxim, of no small importance in democratical governments, that the more extensive the district of election is, the choice will be the more wise and enlightened".[120] The 1790 Constitution of Pennsylvania specified multiple-member districts for the state Senate and required their boundaries to follow county lines.[121]

19th century

edit

A PR system that uses single transferable votes was invented in 1819 by an English schoolmaster, Thomas Wright Hill, who devised a "plan of election" for the committee of the Society for Literary and Scientific Improvement in Birmingham that used not only transfers of surplus votes from winners but also from losers, a refinement that later both Andræ and Hare initially omitted. But the procedure seemed unsuitable for a public election and was not publicised. In 1839, Hill's son, Rowland Hill, recommended the concept for public elections in Adelaide, and a simple process was used in which voters were allowed to form as many groups as there were representatives to be elected, each group electing one representative.[118]

The Sainte-Laguë method of party-list proportional representation was first described in 1832 by the American statesman and senator Daniel Webster.

The list plan system was conceived by Thomas Gilpin, a retired paper-mill owner, in a paper he read to the American Philosophical Society in Philadelphia in 1844: "On the representation of minorities of electors to act with the majority in elected assemblies". It ensured at least one popularly elected member for each part of a multi-member district and also district-wide party-balanced representation.[122] It was never put into practical use, but even as late as 1914 it was put forward as a way to elect the U.S. electoral college delegates and for local elections.[118][123][122]

A practical election using the single transferable vote system (a combination of preferential voting and multi-member districts) was devised in Denmark by Carl Andræ, a mathematician, and first used there in 1855, making it the oldest PR system.

STV was also invented (apparently independently) in the UK in 1857 by Thomas Hare, a London barrister, in his pamphlet The Machinery of Representation and expanded on in his 1859 Treatise on the Election of Representatives. The scheme was enthusiastically taken up by John Stuart Mill, ensuring international interest. The 1865 edition of the book included the transfer of preferences from dropped candidates and the STV method was essentially complete, although Hare pictured the entire British Isles as one single district. Mill proposed it to the House of Commons in 1867, but the British parliament rejected it. The name of the system evolved from "Mr. Hare's scheme" to "proportional representation", then "proportional representation with the single transferable vote", and finally, by the end of the 19th century, to "the single transferable vote". Such a system was well suited to the British political tradition. STV was preferred in the English-speaking world because traditionally votes were cast directly for individuals.[124] STV was later adopted for national elections in Malta (1921), the Republic of Ireland (1921) and Australia (1948).

In Australia, the political activist Catherine Helen Spence became an enthusiast of STV and an author on the subject. Through her influence and the efforts of the Tasmanian politician Andrew Inglis Clark, Tasmania became an early pioneer of the system, electing the world's first legislators through STV in 1896, prior to its federation into Australia.[125]

20th century

edit

In Russia, Leon Trotsky had proposed the election of a new Soviet presidium with other socialist parties on the basis of proportional representation in September 1917.[126]

In the UK, the 1917 Speaker's Conference recommended STV for all multi-seat Westminster constituencies, but it was only applied to university constituencies, lasting from 1918 until 1950 when the last of those constituencies were abolished.

In Ireland, STV was used in 1918 in the Dublin University constituency, and was introduced for devolved elections in 1921.

STV is currently used for two national lower houses of parliament, Ireland, since independence (as the Irish Free State) in 1922,[6] and Malta, since 1921, long before independence in 1966.[127] In Ireland, two attempts were made by Fianna Fáil governments to abolish STV and replace it with the first-past-the-post plurality system. Both attempts were rejected by voters in referendums held in 1959 and again in 1968. STV is also prescribed for all other elections in Ireland including that of the presidency, although it is there effectively the alternative vote, as it is an election with a single winner.

It is also used for the Northern Ireland Assembly and European and local authorities, Scottish local authorities, some New Zealand and Australian local authorities,[48] the Tasmanian (since 1907) and Australian Capital Territory assemblies, where the method is known as Hare-Clark,[128] and the city council in Cambridge, Massachusetts (since 1941).[11][129]

The D'Hondt method was devised in 1878 by Belgian mathematician Victor D'Hondt as a way to allocate seats in a party-list PR system. Some Swiss cantons started using it to produce PR, beginning with Ticino in 1890. Victor Considerant, a utopian socialist, described a similar system in an 1892 book. Many European countries adopted similar systems during or after World War I. List PR was favoured on the Continent because the use of lists in elections, the scrutin de liste, was already widespread. Each uses one of a variety of methods of allocating seats – the D'Hondt method, the Sainte-Laguë method or a different one.

Through the late 1800s and early 1900s, political reformers were involved in discussion and squabbles on the alternative system that would replace the first-past-the-post or block voting systems that were being used. Cumulative voting, limited voting, supplementary voting (contingent voting), STV, instant-runoff voting, the Bucklin system of ranked voting, and list PR were used in different places, at the municipal, state or national level in that period. List PR or STV eventually became the preferred alternative electoral method for many jurisdictions by the 1920s. The MMP version of list PR began to be used after the Second World War. District representation, proportionality of the results, the rate of wasted votes, the acceptable level of complication for voters and election officials, quickness of announcement of results and other aspects were often valued differently by the different reformers and by the elected governments who usually had the power to make decisions over electoral system. There is thus a wide range of PR systems used by the countries in the world that have adopted PR.[130][131]

PR is used by a majority of the world's 33 most robust democracies with populations of at least two million people – 23 use PR (20 use list PR, two use MMP and one uses STV), while only six use plurality or a majoritarian system (runoff or instant runoff) for elections to the legislative assembly; and four use parallel systems, which usually involves some members being elected through PR.[132] PR dominates Europe, including Germany and most of northern and eastern Europe; it is also used for European Parliament elections. France adopted PR at the end of World War II, but discarded it in 1958; it was used for parliament elections in 1986. Switzerland has the most widespread use of proportional representation, as it is used there to elect not only national legislatures but also cantonal and communal legislatures.

PR is less common in the English-speaking world, especially at the national level. Malta and Ireland use STV for election of legislators. Australia uses it for senate elections. New Zealand adopted MMP in 1993. Gibraltar uses quasi-PR, limited voting.

The UK, Canada and India use first-past-the-post systems for legislative elections, but even then its use is a fairly recent phenomenon, with single-member plurality used exclusively in the UK only since 1958, in Canada only since 1968, and in India only since 1950.[133][134] STV was used to elect British university MPs prior to 1958. As well, a variety of election systems were used in Canada to elect provincial legislators. STV was used to elect some provincial legislators in Alberta from 1924 to 1955, and in Manitoba from 1920 to 1953. In both provinces, the alternative vote (AV) was used in rural areas alongside STV in the major urban centres. First-past-the-post was re-adopted in Alberta by the dominant party for reasons of political advantage. In Manitoba, a principal reason given was to address under-representation of Winnipeg in the provincial legislature (which could have otherwise been addressed by adding more members to urban districts).[118]: 223–234 [135]

STV has some history in the United States. Between 1915 and 1962, twenty-four cities used the system for at least one election. In many cities, minority parties and other groups used STV to break up single-party monopolies on elective office. One of the most famous cases is New York City, where a coalition of Republicans and others pursued the adoption of STV in 1936 as part of an effort to free the city from control by the Tammany Hall political machine. Under the new electoral system, Tammany Hall's power was abated but NYC dropped STV in 1946 after only five elections.[136][137] Another famous case is Cincinnati, Ohio, where, in 1924, Democrats and Progressive-wing Republicans secured the adoption of a council–manager charter with STV elections in order to dislodge the Republican machine of Rudolph K. Hynicka. Although Cincinnati's council–manager system survives, Republicans and other disaffected groups replaced STV with plurality-at-large voting in 1957.[138] From 1870 to 1980, Illinois used a semi-proportional cumulative voting system to elect its House of Representatives. Each district across the state elected both Republicans and Democrats year-after-year.

Cambridge, Massachusetts (STV) and Peoria, Illinois (cumulative voting) have used PR for many years. Illinois used cumulative voting for decades in its state elections.[139][140]

San Francisco (in most elections before 1977 and between 1980 and 1999) had citywide elections in which people cast multiple votes – sometimes for as many as nine candidates but usually for five or six – simultaneously (block voting), producing some aspects of PR through the use of a multi-member district. San Francisco used preferential voting (Bucklin voting) in its 1917 city election.

List of countries using proportional representation

edit
List of countries using proportional representation to elect the lower (or only) house of national legislature
 
  Party-list PR
  Single transferable vote
  Mixed-member proportional
  Mixed-member majoritarian

Eighty-five countries in the world use a proportional electoral system to fill a nationally elected legislative body.

The table below lists those countries and gives information on the specific PR system that is in use.

Detailed information on electoral systems applying to the first chamber of the legislature is maintained by the ACE Electoral Knowledge Network.[141][142] Countries using PR as part of a mixed-member majoritarian (e.g. parallel voting) system are not included.

Country Body Type of body Type of proportional system List type

(if applicable)

Variation of open lists

(if applicable)

Allocating formula Electoral threshold Constit­uencies Governmental system Notes
Albania Parliament (Kuvendi) Unicameral national legislature Party-list PR Open list ? D'Hondt method 4% nationally or 2.5% in a district Counties
Algeria People's National Assembly Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR Open list ? Hare quota 5% of votes in respective district.[143]
Angola National Assembly Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR Closed list D'Hondt method [citation needed] 5 member districts and nationwide Double simultaneous vote use to elect the President and the National Assembly at the same election.
Argentina Chamber of Deputies Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR Closed list D'Hondt method 3% of registered voters Provinces
Armenia National Assembly Unicameral national legislature Party-list PR with majority jackpot and minority jackpot [144] Open list ? Largest remainder method (? quota) 5% (parties), 7% (blocs) Party lists run-off, but only if necessary to ensure stable majority of 54% if it is not achieved either immediately (one party) or through building a coalition.[145][146] If a party would win more than 2/3 seats, at least 1/3 seats are distributed to the other parties.
Closed list Largest remainder method (? quota)
Aruba (Kingdom of the Netherlands) Parliament Unicameral constituent country legislature Party-list PR Open list
Australia Senate Upper house of national legislature Single transferable vote States and territories of Australia Federal parliamentary constitutional monarchy
Austria National Council Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR Open list More open:

14% on the district level

Hare quota 4% Single-member districts within federal states (Länder) Parliamentary republic
Open list More open:

10% on the regional (state) level

Hare quota Federal states (Länder)
Open list More open: 7% of the on the federal level D'Hondt method Single federal (nationwide) constituency
Belgium Chamber of Representatives Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR Open list ? D'Hondt method 5% Electoral districts Federal parliamentary constitutional monarchy
Benin Party-list PR Closed list
Bolivia Chamber of Deputies Lower house of national legislature Additional member system – MMP (fixed number of seats – no leveling seats) Closed list 3% Unitary presidential republic Ballots use the double simultaneous vote: voters cast a single vote for a presidential candidate and their party's list and local candidates at the same time (vote splitting is not possible/allowed)
Chamber of Senators Upper house of national legislature Party-list PR Closed list D'Hondt method
Bosnia and Herzegovina House of Representatives Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR Open list ? Sainte-Laguë method Electoral districts Federal parliamentary directorial republic
Brazil Chamber of Deputies Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR Open list ? D'Hondt method 2% distributed in at least 9 federation units with at least 1% of the valid votes in each one of them States and federal district Presidential Republic
Bulgaria National Assembly Unicameral national legislature Party-list PR Open list ? D'Hondt method 4% Electoral districts Unitary parliamentary republic
Burkina Faso National Assembly Unicameral national legislature Party-list PR Closed list
Burundi National Assembly Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR Closed list 2%
Cape Verde National Assembly Unicameral national legislature Party-list PR Closed list
Chile Chamber of Deputies Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR Open list
Colombia Chamber of Representatives Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR Closed list Unitary presidential republic
Senate Upper house of national legislature Party-list PR Closed list
Costa Rica Party-list PR Closed list
Croatia Party-list PR Open list 5%
Cyprus Party-list PR Open list
Czech Republic[73] Party-list PR Open list Imperiali quota 5%
Denmark Folketing Unicameral national legislature Party-list PR Open list Sainte-Laguë method for leveling seats 2% Parliamentary system 135 constituency seats, 40 leveling seats
Dominican Republic Party-list PR Closed list
East Timor Party-list PR
Ecuador National Congress Unicameral national legislature Party-list PR Closed list Sainte-Laguë method
El Salvador Legislative Assembly Unicameral national legislature Party-list PR Open list
Equatorial Guinea Party-list PR
Estonia Party-list PR Open list 5%
European Union European Parliament Lower house of supranational legislature Party-list PR in 25 member states Open list in 19 countries
Closed list (Germany, France, Portugal, Spain, Hungary, Romania)
Single transferable vote in Ireland and Malta
Faroe Islands Party-list PR
Fiji Party-list PR 5%
Finland Party-list PR
Germany Federal Assembly (Bundestag) Lower house of national legislature Mixed-member PR Closed list Sainte-Laguë method 5% regionally
Greece Parliament (Boule) Unicameral national legislature Majority bonus system (reinforced party-list proportionality) Open list Apart from snap elections Hare quota 3% nationally + tiered bonus of the seats (from 25% of the votes a seat is added for each 0.5% the first party gets) Prefectures (apart from Attica and Thessaloniki) Parliamentary republic
Greenland Party-list PR
Guatemala Party-list PR
Guinea-Bissau Party-list PR
Guyana Party-list PR
Honduras Party-list PR
Iceland Party-list PR
Indonesia House of Representatives Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR Open list Sainte-Laguë method 4% Constituency (electoral districts: groups of regencies and cities in Indonesian provinces) Unitary presidential constitutional republic
Ireland Dáil Éireann Lower house of national legislature Single transferable vote
seats with 3-5 members
Unitary parliamentary republic
Israel Knesset Unicameral national legislature Party-list PR 3.25% Unitary parliamentary republic
Kosovo Party-list PR Sainte-Laguë method
Latvia Saeima Unicameral national legislature Party-list PR Open list Most open Sainte-Laguë method 5% 5 multi-member constituencies consisting of municipalities[147] Parliamentary republic
Lebanon Party-list PR
Lesotho Mixed-member PR variant using a mixed single vote
Liechtenstein Landtag Unicameral national legislature Party-list PR 8% Constituencies (electoral districts) Parliamentary system
Luxembourg Chamber of Deputies Unicameral national legislature Party-list PR Open list Panachage Hagenbach-Bischoff system Constituencies Parliamentary system
Macedonia Party-list PR
Malta Single transferable vote
Moldova Party-list PR 6%
Montenegro Party-list PR 3%
Mozambique Party-list PR
Namibia Party-list PR
Netherlands House of Representatives Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR Open list More open: 25% of the quota for one seat (0.167%) D'Hondt method 0.667% (1/150) None (votes are tallied in a single nationwide constituency) Parliamentary system
New Zealand House of Representatives Unicameral national legislature Mixed-member PR Sainte-Laguë method 5% or 1 district won
Nepal Mixed-member PR Sainte-Laguë method 3%
Norway Party-list PR Sainte-Laguë method 4%
Palestine Party-list PR
Paraguay Party-list PR
Peru Party-list PR 5%
Poland Sejm Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR Open list D'Hondt method 5% threshold or more for single parties, 8% or more for coalitions or 0% or more for minorities
Portugal Party-list PR Closed list
Romania Party-list PR Closed list
Rwanda Party-list PR Closed list
San Marino Party-list PR with contingent majority jackpot runoff Open list 3.5% If needed to ensure a stable majority, the two best-placed parties participate in a run-off vote to receive a majority bonus.
São Tomé and Príncipe Party-list PR Closed list
Serbia Party-list PR Closed list 3%
Sint Maarten Party-list PR Open list
Slovakia Party-list PR Open list 5%
Slovenia Party-list PR Open list Largest remainder (Droop quota) 4%
d'Hondt method 4%
South Africa Party-list PR Closed list
at large
Spain Congress of Deputies Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR[148] Closed list D'Hondt method 3% Provinces of Spain Parliamentary system
Sri Lanka Parliament Party-list PR[149][150][151] Open list
(District lists elect 196/225 seats)
Panachage
(up to 3 preference votes)[152]
Hare quota 5%
(per constituency)
Constituencies (electoral districts) Semi-presidential system
Closed list
(National list to elect 29/225 seats)
Hare quota No threshold None
(single nationwide constituency)
Suriname National Assembly Party-list PR[153] Open list Most open D'Hondt method No threshold Districts of Suriname Assembly-independent republic
Sweden Riksdag Party-list PR[154][155] Open list More open
(5% of the party vote to override the default party-list)[156]
Sainte-Laguë method 4% nationally or 12%
in a given constituency
Counties of Sweden
(some counties are further subdivided)
Parliamentary system Leveling seats
Switzerland National Council Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR[157] Open list Panachage Hagenbach-Bischoff system No threshold Cantons of Switzerland Semi-direct democracy under an assembly-independent[158][159] directorial republic
Council of States
(only to elect Councillors in:
Party-list PR[161] Open list Most open ? No threshold[162] None
(single cantonwide constituency)[163]
Thailand House of Representatives Lower house of national legislature Mixed-member PR[164] Closed list Largest remainder method (? quota) No threshold None
(single nationwide constituency)
Parliamentary system
under a constitutional monarchy
Next elections are to be held under parallel voting
Togo National Assembly Party-list PR[165] Closed list Highest averages method (?) No threshold Constituencies Presidential system
Tunisia Assembly of the Representatives of the People Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR[166] Closed list Largest remainder method (? quota) No threshold Constituencies Semi-presidential system
Turkey Grand National Assembly Unicameral national legislature Party-list PR[167] Closed list D'Hondt method 7% Provinces of Turkey
(some provinces are further subdivided)
Presidential system
Uruguay Chamber of Representatives Lower house of national legislature Party-list PR[168][169] Closed list D'Hondt method No threshold Departments of Uruguay Presidential system Ballots use the double simultaneous vote, the same ballot is used for electing the president (first round) and the two chambers
Chamber of Senators Upper house of national legislature None
(single nationwide constituency)

Incentives for choosing an electoral system

edit

Changing the electoral system requires the agreement of a majority of the currently selected legislators, who were chosen using the incumbent electoral system. Therefore, an interesting question is what incentives make current legislators support a new electoral system, particularly a PR system.

Many political scientists argue that PR was adopted by parties on the right as a strategy to survive amid suffrage expansion, democratization and the rise of workers' parties. According to Stein Rokkan in a seminal 1970 study, parties on the right opted to adopt PR as a way to survive as competitive parties in situations when the parties on the right were not united enough to exist under majoritarian systems.[170] This argument was formalized and supported by Carles Boix in a 1999 study.[171] Amel Ahmed notes that prior to the adoption of PR, many electoral systems were based on majority or plurality rule, and that these systems risked eradicating parties on the right in areas where the working class was large in numbers. He therefore argues that parties on the right adopted PR as a way to ensure that they would survive as potent political forces amid suffrage expansion.[172] A 2021 study linked the adoption of PR to incumbent fears of revolutionary threats.[173]

In contrast, other scholars argue that the choice to adopt PR was also due to a demand by parties on the left to ensure a foothold in politics, as well as to encourage a consensual system that would help the left realize its preferred economic policies.[174] The pressure to change may become so great that the government feels it must give in to the demand, even if it itself does not benefit from the change. This is the same process by which women's suffrage was achieved in many countries.[175]

See also

edit

Notes

edit
  1. ^ STV was used in 2010 to elect 25 members at large in the 2010 Icelandic Constitutional Assembly election.

References

edit
  1. ^ a b c d Mill, John Stuart (1861). "Chapter VII, Of True and False Democracy; Representation of All, and Representation of the Majority only". Considerations on Representative Government. London: Parker, Son, & Bourn.
  2. ^ Laakso, Markku (1980). "Electoral Justice as a Criterion for Different Systems of Proportional Representation". Scandinavian Political Studies. 3 (3). Wiley: 249–264. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9477.1980.tb00248.x. ISSN 0080-6757.
  3. ^ The European parliament: Electoral procedures https://www.europarl.europa.eu/factsheets/en/sheet/21/the-european-parliament-electoral-procedures accessed December 13, 2024
  4. ^ ACE Project: The Electoral Knowledge Network. "Electoral Systems Comparative Data, Table by Question". Retrieved 20 November 2014.
  5. ^ a b Amy, Douglas J. "How Proportional Representation Elections Work". FairVote. Retrieved 26 October 2017.
  6. ^ a b c Gallagher, Michael. "Ireland: The Archetypal Single Transferable Vote System" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 20 October 2017. Retrieved 26 October 2014.
  7. ^ Hirczy de Miño, Wolfgang; Lane, John (1999). "Malta: STV in a two-party system" (PDF). Retrieved 24 July 2014.
  8. ^ "Rajya Sabha Introduction".
  9. ^ Algeria's largest district has 37 deputies (p. 15): https://www.cartercenter.org/resources/pdfs/news/peace_publications/election_reports/algeria-may2012-final-rpt.pdf
  10. ^ "Proportional Representation (PR)". ACE Electoral Knowledge Network. Retrieved 9 April 2014.
  11. ^ a b c Amy, Douglas J. "A Brief History of Proportional Representation in the United States". FairVote. Retrieved 16 October 2015.
  12. ^ "Results: NSW Election 2019". ABC Elections. Archived from the original on 24 March 2019. Retrieved 23 March 2019
  13. ^ a b "Electoral Commission of Malta".
  14. ^ "2023 NSW State election results".
  15. ^ a b c d e Forder, James (2011). The case against voting reform. Oxford: Oneworld Publications. ISBN 978-1-85168-825-8.
  16. ^ Abbott, Lewis F. British Democracy: Its Restoration and Extension. ISR/Kindle Books, 2019. ISBN 9780906321522. Chapter 7, "Electoral System Reform: Increasing Competition and Voter Choice and Influence".
  17. ^ Report of meeting on Proportional representation or effective voting, p. 25. https://onlinebooks.library.upenn.edu/webbin/book/lookupid?key=ha100618520
  18. ^ 2020 Irish general election]]
  19. ^ "Holyrood's AMS Voting System Explained".
  20. ^ Koriyama, Y.; Macé, A.; Laslier, J.-F.; Treibich, R. (2013). "Optimal apportionment". Journal of Political Economy. 121 (3): 584–608. doi:10.1086/670380. S2CID 10158811.
  21. ^ Amy, Douglas. "Proportional Representation Voting Systems". Fairvote.org. Takoma Park. Archived from the original on 14 June 2021. Retrieved 25 August 2017.
  22. ^ a b c d Norris, Pippa (1997). "Choosing Electoral Systems: Proportional, Majoritarian and Mixed Systems" (PDF). International Political Science Review. 18 (3). Harvard University: 297–312. doi:10.1177/019251297018003005. ISSN 0192-5121. S2CID 9523715. Archived from the original on 5 July 2015. Retrieved 9 April 2014.
  23. ^ Rallings, Colin; Thrasher, Michael. "The 2005 general election: analysis of the results" (PDF). Electoral Commission, Research, Electoral data. London: Electoral Commission. Archived from the original (PDF) on 20 October 2017. Retrieved 29 March 2015.
  24. ^ a b c Commission On Electoral Reform, Hansard Society for Parliamentary Government (1976). "Report of the Hansard Society Commission on Electoral Reform". Hansard Society. London.
  25. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l m n o p q r "Electoral System Design: the New International IDEA Handbook". International Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance. 2005. Retrieved 9 April 2014.
  26. ^ "1993 Canadian Federal Election Results". University of British Columbia. Archived from the original on 30 August 2017. Retrieved 25 January 2016.
  27. ^ "Election 2015 – BBC News". BBC. Retrieved 11 May 2015.
  28. ^ da Costa, Ana Nicolaci; Greenfield, Charlotte (23 September 2017). "New Zealand's ruling party ahead after poll but kingmaker in no rush to decide". Reuters.
  29. ^ Roberts, Iain (29 June 2010). "People in broad church parties should think twice before attacking coalitions". Liberal Democrat Voice. Retrieved 29 July 2014.
  30. ^ a b c "A look at the evidence". Fair Vote Canada. Retrieved 2 January 2019.
  31. ^ Amy, Douglas J. "Single Transferable Vote Or Choice Voting". FairVote. Archived from the original on 14 June 2021. Retrieved 9 April 2014.
  32. ^ "Electoral Reform Society's evidence to the Joint Committee on the Draft Bill for House of Lords Reform". Electoral Reform Society. 21 October 2011. Retrieved 10 May 2015.
  33. ^ Harris, Paul (20 November 2011). "'America is better than this': paralysis at the top leaves voters desperate for change". The Guardian. Retrieved 17 November 2014.
  34. ^ Krugman, Paul (19 May 2012). "Going To Extreme". The Conscience of a Liberal, Paul Krugman Blog. The New York Times Co. Retrieved 24 November 2014.
  35. ^ Drutman, Lee (2020). "The Paradox of Partisanship". Breaking the Two-Party Doom Loop. Oxford University Press. pp. 35–57. doi:10.1093/oso/9780190913854.003.0003. ISBN 978-0-19-091385-4.
  36. ^ "As Partisan Hostility Grows, Signs of Frustration with the Two-Party System". 9 August 2022.
  37. ^ "Political Stability".
  38. ^ a b c d e f g Mollison, Denis. "Fair votes in practice STV for Westminster" (PDF). Heriot Watt University. Retrieved 3 June 2014.
  39. ^ "Democrats' Edge in House Popular Vote Would Have Increased if All Seats Had Been Contested". FairVote. Archived from the original on 28 September 2015. Retrieved 7 July 2014.
  40. ^ Cox, Gary W.; Fiva, Jon H.; Smith, Daniel M. (2016). "The Contraction Effect: How Proportional Representation Affects Mobilization and Turnout" (PDF). The Journal of Politics. 78 (4): 1249–1263. doi:10.1086/686804. hdl:11250/2429132. S2CID 55400647.
  41. ^ Karp, Jeffrey A.; Banducci, Susan A. (2008). "Political Efficacy and Participation in Twenty-Seven Democracies: How Electoral Systems Shape Political Behaviour". British Journal of Political Science. 38 (2): 311–334. doi:10.1017/S0007123408000161. hdl:10036/64393. S2CID 55486399.
  42. ^ "Voters dislike disproportionality in electoral systems – even when it benefits the party they support". 29 January 2020.
  43. ^ a b c d Amy, Douglas J (2002). Real Choices / New Voices, How Proportional Representation Elections Could Revitalize American Democracy. Columbia University Press. ISBN 9780231125499.
  44. ^ Mollison, Denis (2010). "Fair votes in practice: STV for Westminster". Heriot-Watt University. Retrieved 3 June 2014.
  45. ^ Scheppele, Kim Lane (13 April 2014). "Legal But Not Fair (Hungary)". The Conscience of a Liberal, Paul Krugman Blog. The New York Times Co. Retrieved 12 July 2014.
  46. ^ Office for Democratic Institutions and Human Rights (11 July 2014). "Hungary, Parliamentary Elections, 6 April 2014: Final Report". OSCE.
  47. ^ "Voting Counts: Electoral Reform for Canada" (PDF). Law Commission of Canada. 2004. p. 22.
  48. ^ a b "Single Transferable Vote". London: Electoral Reform Society. Retrieved 28 July 2014.
  49. ^ Humphreys, John H (1911). Proportional Representation, A Study in Methods of Election. London: Methuen & Co.Ltd.
  50. ^ "Evenredige vertegenwoordiging". www.parlement.com (in Dutch). Retrieved 28 January 2020.
  51. ^ "Electoral reform in Chile: Tie breaker". The Economist. 14 February 2015. Retrieved 11 April 2018.
  52. ^ "National projections" (PDF). Monopoly Politics 2014 and the Fair Voting Solution. FairVote. Archived from the original (PDF) on 24 September 2015. Retrieved 9 July 2014.
  53. ^ a b Laver, Michael (1998). "A new electoral system for Ireland?" (PDF). The Policy Institute, Trinity College Dublin.
  54. ^ "Joint Committee on the Constitution" (PDF). Dublin: Houses of the Oireachtas. July 2010.
  55. ^ https://www.ourcommons.ca/content/Committee/421/ERRE/Brief/BR8391757/br-external/2PedenR-e.pdf [bare URL PDF]
  56. ^ "Turkey reduces election threshold to 7 percent – Türkiye News". Hürriyet Daily News. April 2022. Retrieved 19 March 2023.
  57. ^ Lubell, Maayan (11 March 2014). "Israel ups threshold for Knesset seats despite opposition boycott". Thomson Reuters. Retrieved 10 July 2014.
  58. ^ Benoit, Kenneth. "Which Electoral Formula Is the Most Proportional?" (PDF). doi:10.1093/oxfordjournals.pan.a029822. Archived from the original (PDF) on 24 June 2010
  59. ^ a b "Party Magnitude and Candidate Selection —". aceproject.org.
  60. ^ "Party Magnitude and Candidate Selection". ACE Electoral Knowledge Network.
  61. ^ O'Kelly, Michael. "The fall of Fianna Fáil in the 2011 Irish general election". Significance. Royal Statistical Society, American Statistical Association. Archived from the original on 6 August 2014.
  62. ^ "General Elections 2011 Ireland".
  63. ^ Hoag and Hallett, Proportional Representation, p. 74
  64. ^ Karpov, Alexander (2008). "Measurement of disproportionality in proportional representation systems". Mathematical and Computer Modelling. 48 (9–10): 1421–1438. doi:10.1016/j.mcm.2008.05.027.
  65. ^ "2020 GENERAL ELECTION – OFFICIAL RESULTS AND STATISTICS". ElectionResults.govt.nz. Electoral Commission. 30 November 2020.
  66. ^ Wada, Junichiro (2016). "Apportionment behind the veil of uncertainty". The Japanese Economic Review. 67 (3): 348–360. doi:10.1111/jere.12093. S2CID 156608434.
  67. ^ https://www.researchgate.net/publication/349468714_New_indexes_for_measuring_electoral_disproportionality, p. 372
  68. ^ Canadian House of Commons Special Committee on Electoral Reform (December 2016). "Strengthening Democracy in Canada: Principles, Process and Public Engagement for Electoral Reform".
  69. ^ As counted from the table in http://www.wahlrecht.de/ausland/europa.htm [in German]; "Vorzugsstimme(n)" means "open list".
  70. ^ "Party List PR". Electoral Reform Society. Retrieved 23 May 2016.
  71. ^ Gibson, Gordon (2003). Fixing Canadian Democracy. The Fraser Institute. p. 76. ISBN 9780889752016.
  72. ^ Gallagher, Michael; Mitchell, Paul (2005). The Politics of Electoral Systems. Oxford, New York: Oxford University Press. p. 11. ISBN 978-0-19-925756-0.
  73. ^ a b Smrek, Michal (2023). "Mavericks or Loyalists? Popular Ballot Jumpers and Party Discipline in the Flexible-List PR Context". Political Research Quarterly. 76 (1): 323–336. doi:10.1177/10659129221087961.
  74. ^ "The Parliamentary Electoral System in Denmark". Copenhagen: Ministry of the Interior and Health. 2011. Archived from the original on 23 November 2017. Retrieved 1 September 2014.
  75. ^ "The main features of the Norwegian electoral system". Oslo: Ministry of Local Government and Modernisation. 6 July 2017. Retrieved 1 September 2014.
  76. ^ "The Swedish electoral system". Stockholm: Election Authority. 2011. Archived from the original on 18 August 2014. Retrieved 1 September 2014.
  77. ^ ACE Project Electoral Knowledge Network. "Mixed Systems". Retrieved 29 June 2016.
  78. ^ Massicotte, Louis (2004). In Search of Compensatory Mixed Electoral System for Québec (PDF) (Report). Archived from the original (PDF) on 24 December 2019. Retrieved 29 December 2023.
  79. ^ Bochsler, Daniel (13 May 2010). "Chapter 5, How Party Systems Develop in Mixed Electoral Systems". Territory and Electoral Rules in Post-Communist Democracies. Palgrave Macmillan. ISBN 9780230281424.
  80. ^ "Electoral Systems and the Delimitation of Constituencies". International Foundation for Electoral Systems. 2 July 2009.
  81. ^ Moser, Robert G. (December 2004). "Mixed electoral systems and electoral system effects: controlled comparison and cross-national analysis". Electoral Studies. 23 (4): 575–599. doi:10.1016/S0261-3794(03)00056-8.
  82. ^ Massicotte, Louis (September 1999). "Mixed electoral systems: a conceptual and empirical survey". Electoral Studies. 18 (3): 341–366. doi:10.1016/S0261-3794(98)00063-8.
  83. ^ "Additional Member System". London: Electoral Reform Society. Retrieved 16 October 2015.
  84. ^ "MMP Voting System". Wellington: Electoral Commission New Zealand. 2011. Retrieved 10 August 2014.
  85. ^ "Deutschland hat ein neues Wahlrecht" (in German). Zeit Online. 22 February 2013.
  86. ^ "Report of the Electoral Commission on the Review of the MMP Voting System". Wellington: Electoral Commission New Zealand. 2011. Archived from the original on 7 July 2014. Retrieved 10 August 2014.
  87. ^ Graham, Sean (2016). Dual-Member Mixed Proportional: A New Electoral System for Canada (Thesis). University of Alberta. doi:10.7939/R3-QPPP-B676. Retrieved 10 August 2022.
  88. ^ Hodgson, Antony (21 January 2016). "Why a referendum on electoral reform would be undemocratic". The Tyee.
  89. ^ Campbell, Kerry (15 April 2016). "P.E.I. electoral reform committee proposes ranked ballot". CBC News.
  90. ^ Elections PEI (7 November 2016). "Plebiscite Results". Archived from the original on 8 November 2016. Retrieved 26 October 2017.
  91. ^ Bradley, Susan (7 November 2016). "P.E.I. plebiscite favours mixed member proportional representation". CBC News.
  92. ^ Eby, David (30 May 2018). "How We Vote: 2018 Electoral Reform Referendum Report and Recommendations of the Attorney General" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 31 August 2018. Retrieved 9 June 2018.
  93. ^ McElroy, Justin (2 June 2018). "Know your voting systems: three types of electoral reform on B.C.'s ballot". CBC News.
  94. ^ "2018 Referendum on Electoral Reform: Voting Results Available". Elections BC. 20 December 2018. Retrieved 1 November 2020.
  95. ^ Pukelsheim, Friedrich (September 2009). "Zurich's New Apportionment" (PDF). German Research. 31 (2): 10–12. doi:10.1002/germ.200990024. Retrieved 10 August 2014.
  96. ^ a b Balinski, Michel (February 2008). "Fair Majority Voting (or How to Eliminate Gerrymandering)". The American Mathematical Monthly. 115 (2): 97–113. doi:10.1080/00029890.2008.11920503. S2CID 1139441. Retrieved 10 August 2014.
  97. ^ Akartunalı, Kerem; Knight, Philip A. (June 2017). "Network models and biproportional rounding for fair seat allocations in the UK elections". Annals of Operations Research. 253 (1). University of Strathclyde: 1–19. doi:10.1007/s10479-016-2323-0. ISSN 0254-5330. S2CID 30623821.
  98. ^ "Fair Voting/Proportional Representation". FairVote. Archived from the original on 8 December 2015. Retrieved 9 April 2014.
  99. ^ a b c Tideman, Nicolaus (1995). "The Single Transferable Vote". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 9 (1): 27–38. doi:10.1257/jep.9.1.27.
  100. ^ O’Neill, Jeffrey C. (July 2006). "Comments on the STV Rules Proposed by British Columbia". Voting Matters (22). Retrieved 10 August 2013.
  101. ^ Model City Charter National Civic League. 9th edition. 2021
  102. ^ Barber. Proportional Representation and Electoral Reform in Ohio. p. 191.
  103. ^ Farrell, David M.; McAllister, Ian (2006). The Australian Electoral System: Origins, Variations, and Consequences. Sydney: UNSW Press. ISBN 978-0868408583.
  104. ^ "Referendum 2011: A look at the STV system". The New Zealand Herald. Auckland: The New Zealand Herald. 1 November 2011. Retrieved 21 November 2014.
  105. ^ "Change the Way We Elect? Round Two of the Debate". The Tyee. Vancouver. 30 April 2009. Retrieved 21 November 2014.
  106. ^ McLean, Iain, "Voting", in Robin Wilson, and Amirouche Moktefi (eds), "The Mathematical World of Charles L. Dodgson (Lewis Carroll)” (Oxford, 2019; online edn, Oxford Academic, 17 Apr.
  107. ^ Negotiated Consensus https://gregblonder.medium.com/negotiated-consensus-bfde8bde5a20
  108. ^ C. L. Dodgson, "The Principles of Parliamentary Representation: Supplement" (Oxford 1885), p7, https://ia801308.us.archive.org/26/items/principlesofparl00carr/principlesofparl00carr_jpg.pdf
  109. ^ Poundstone, William, "Gaming the Vote: Why Elections Aren't Fair (and What We Can Do About It)", Hill and Wang, New York, 2008, ISBN 9780809048922
  110. ^ Brill, Markus; Laslier, Jean-François; Skowron, Piotr (2016). "Multiwinner Approval Rules as Apportionment Methods". arXiv:1611.08691 [cs.GT].
  111. ^ Aziz, Haris; Gaspers, Serge; Gudmundsson, Joachim; Mackenzie, Simon; Mattei, Nicholas; Walsh, Toby (2014). "Computational Aspects of Multi-Winner Approval Voting". Proceedings of the 2015 International Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems. pp. 107–115. arXiv:1407.3247v1. ISBN 978-1-4503-3413-6.
  112. ^ Faliszewski, Piotr; Skowron, Piotr; Szufa, Stanisław; Talmon, Nimrod (8 May 2019). "Proportional Representation in Elections: STV vs PAV". Proceedings of the 18th International Conference on Autonomous Agents and MultiAgent Systems. AAMAS '19. Richland, SC: International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems: 1946–1948. ISBN 978-1-4503-6309-9.
  113. ^ Lackner, Martin; Skowron, Piotr (2023). Multi-Winner Voting with Approval Preferences. SpringerBriefs in Intelligent Systems. arXiv:2007.01795. doi:10.1007/978-3-031-09016-5. ISBN 978-3-031-09015-8. S2CID 244921148.
  114. ^ "89th Annual Academy Awards of Merit for Achievements during 2017" (PDF). Retrieved 4 April 2016.
  115. ^ "Rule Twenty-Two: Special Rules for the Visual Effects Award". Archived from the original on 14 September 2012. Retrieved 4 April 2016.
  116. ^ Sargent, Felix (19 June 2019). "Opinion: Berkeley's City Council's switch to 're-weighted range voting' adds fairness to the system". Berkeleyside. Retrieved 11 May 2022.
  117. ^ Adams, John (1776). "Thoughts on Government". The Adams Papers Digital Edition. Massachusetts Historical Society. Archived from the original on 27 May 2014. Retrieved 26 July 2014.
  118. ^ a b c d e Hoag, Clarence; Hallett, George (1926). Proportional Representation. New York: The Macmillan Company.
  119. ^ Madison, James. "Notes of Debates in the Federal Convention of 1787, Wednesday, June 6". TeachingAmericanHistory.org. Retrieved 5 August 2014.
  120. ^ Wilson, James (1804). "Vol 2, Part II, Ch.1 Of the constitutions of the United States and of Pennsylvania – Of the legislative department, I, of the election of its members". The Works of the Honourable James Wilson. Constitution Society. Retrieved 5 August 2014.
  121. ^ "Constitution of the Commonwealth of Pennsylvania – 1790, art.I,§ VII, Of districts for electing Senators". Duquesne University. Retrieved 9 December 2014.
  122. ^ a b Swain, Civics for Montana Students, 1912, p. 163
  123. ^ Hoag, Effective Voting (1914), p. 31
  124. ^ Humphreys, Proportional Representation (1911)
  125. ^ Newman, Hare-Clark in Tasmania, p. 7-10
  126. ^ Deutscher, Isaac (5 January 2015). The Prophet: The Life of Leon Trotsky. Verso Books. p. 293. ISBN 978-1-78168-721-5.
  127. ^ Hirczy de Miño, Wolfgang (1997). "Malta: Single-Transferable Vote with Some Twists". ACE Electoral Knowledge Network. Retrieved 5 December 2014.
  128. ^ "The Hare-Clark System of Proportional Representation". Melbourne: Proportional Representation Society of Australia. Retrieved 21 November 2014.
  129. ^ "Adoption of Plan E". Welcome to the City of Cambridge. City of Cambridge, MA. Archived from the original on 13 December 2014. Retrieved 25 November 2014.
  130. ^ Charles Harry John Phillips, Challenges to the Voting System in Canada 1874–1974, University of Western Ontario, PhD thesis, 1976 (available on-line https://ir.lib.uwo.ca/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1860&context=digitizedtheses) https://ir.lib.uwo.ca/digitizedtheses/861/
  131. ^ "Proportional representation systems for Canada".
  132. ^ "Proportional Representation in Most Robust Democracies". Fair Vote: The Center for Voting And Democracy. 7 March 2016. Retrieved 9 October 2017.
  133. ^ "India - First Past the Post on a Grand Scale —".
  134. ^ 1969 Canadian Parliamentary Guide, p. 333-334
  135. ^ Jansen, Harold John (1998). "The Single Transferable Vote in Alberta and Manitoba" (PDF). Library and Archives Canada. University of Alberta. Retrieved 23 March 2015.
  136. ^ Santucci, Jack (10 November 2016). "Party Splits, Not Progressives". American Politics Research. 45 (3): 494–526. doi:10.1177/1532673x16674774. ISSN 1532-673X. S2CID 157400899.
  137. ^ "New York's proportional representation experiment demonstrates potential of fair representation". 18 December 2017.
  138. ^ Barber, Kathleen (1995). Proportional Representation and Election Reform in Ohio. Columbus, OH: Ohio State University Press. ISBN 978-0814206607.
  139. ^ Newman, Brad (11 May 2008). "Two new faces join AC regents | Amarillo.com | Amarillo Globe-News". Amarillo Globe-News. Retrieved 17 May 2015
  140. ^ "Illinois' Drive to Revive Cumulative Voting". FairVote. 21 April 2006. Retrieved 17 May 2015.
  141. ^ "What is the electoral system for Chamber 1 of the national legislature?". ACE Project. Retrieved 24 October 2017.
  142. ^ "What is the electoral system for Chamber 1 of the national legislature?". ACE Project. Retrieved 24 October 2017.
  143. ^ "Final Report on Algeria's Legislative Elections" (pdf). ACE Project. National Democratic Institute. 10 May 2012. Retrieved 10 January 2015.
  144. ^ Following electoral system amendments introduced in April 2021, members of parliament are elected only through closed party lists by party list proportional representation method but with more seats added if leading party takes more than 2/3 of seats or after two-round of voting no party takes more than 54 percent of the seats
  145. ^ "Armenia, Parliamentary Elections, 2 April 2017: Needs Assessment Mission Report". osce.org. Retrieved 30 May 2022.
  146. ^ "DocumentView". www.arlis.am.
  147. ^ "Saeimas vēlēšanu likums". LIKUMI.LV (in Latvian). Section 7. Retrieved 10 June 2022.
  148. ^ "IPU PARLINE database: SPAIN (Congreso de los Diputados), Electoral system". archive.ipu.org.
  149. ^ "IFES Election Guide | Elections: Sri Lanka Parliament 2020". www.electionguide.org.
  150. ^ "IPU PARLINE database: SRI LANKA (Parliament), Electoral system". archive.ipu.org.
  151. ^ "Report of the Post-Election Assessment of Sri Lanka Mission: November 28 – December 2, 2000" (PDF). www.ndi.org. Archived from the original (PDF) on 3 March 2016. Retrieved 12 January 2022.
  152. ^ "Sri Lanka electors can vote for one party, three preferences in 2020 general elections: polls chief". EconomyNext. 4 August 2020.
  153. ^ "IPU PARLINE database: SURINAME (Nationale Assemblee), Electoral system". archive.ipu.org.
  154. ^ "IFES Election Guide | Elections: Sweden Parliament 2018". www.electionguide.org.
  155. ^ "IPU PARLINE database: SWEDEN (Riksdagen), Electoral system". archive.ipu.org.
  156. ^ Swedish Election Authority: Elections in Sweden: The way its done Archived 25 February 2009 at the Wayback Machine (page 16)
  157. ^ "IPU PARLINE database: SWITZERLAND (Nationalrat – Conseil national – Consiglio nazionale), Electoral system". archive.ipu.org.
  158. ^ Shugart, Matthew Søberg (December 2005). "Semi-Presidential Systems: Dual Executive And Mixed Authority Patterns". French Politics. 3 (3): 323–351. doi:10.1057/palgrave.fp.8200087. S2CID 73642272.
  159. ^ Elgie, Robert (2016). "Government Systems, Party Politics, and Institutional Engineering in the Round". Insight Turkey. 18 (4): 79–92. ISSN 1302-177X. JSTOR 26300453.
  160. ^ a b "IFES Election Guide | Elections: Switzerland Council of States 2019". www.electionguide.org.
  161. ^ "IPU PARLINE database: SWITZERLAND (Ständerat – Conseil des Etats – Consiglio degli Stati), Electoral system". archive.ipu.org.
  162. ^ Thresholds moot due to these cantons only electing 2 Councillors
  163. ^ As these cantons only send two members to the Council of States, further subdividing these cantons into constituencies while retaining proportionality would be mathematically impossible)
  164. ^ "Explainer: New rules for the House of Representatives". Bangkok Post. 6 January 2019.
  165. ^ "IPU PARLINE database: TOGO (Assemblée nationale), Electoral system". archive.ipu.org.
  166. ^ "IFES Election Guide | Elections: Tunisia Parliament 2019". www.electionguide.org.
  167. ^ "IFES Election Guide | Elections: Turkey Grand National Assembly 2018". www.electionguide.org.
  168. ^ "IPU PARLINE database: URUGUAY (Cámara de Representantes), Electoral system". archive.ipu.org.
  169. ^ "IPU PARLINE database: URUGUAY (Cámara de Senadores), Electoral system". archive.ipu.org.
  170. ^ Rokkan, Stein (1970). Citizens, elections, parties: approaches to the comparative study of the processes of development. McKay.
  171. ^ Boix, Carles (1999). "Setting the Rules of the Game: The Choice of Electoral Systems in Advanced Democracies". The American Political Science Review. 93 (3): 609–624. doi:10.2307/2585577. hdl:10230/307. ISSN 0003-0554. JSTOR 2585577. S2CID 16429584.
  172. ^ Ahmed, Amel (2012). Democracy and the Politics of Electoral System Choice: Engineering Electoral Dominance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. doi:10.1017/cbo9781139382137. ISBN 9781139382137. S2CID 153171400.
  173. ^ Gjerløw, Haakon; Rasmussen, Magnus B. (2021). "Revolution, Elite Fear, and Electoral Institutions". Comparative Politics. 54 (4): 595–620. doi:10.5129/001041522x16316387001621. S2CID 244107337.
  174. ^ Cusack, Thomas R.; Iversen, Torben; Soskice, David (2007). "Economic Interests and the Origins of Electoral Systems". The American Political Science Review. 101 (3): 373–391. doi:10.1017/S0003055407070384. hdl:10419/51231. ISSN 0003-0554. JSTOR 27644455. S2CID 2799521.
  175. ^ Bowler and Grofman, Elections in Australia, Ireland and Malta

Further reading

edit

Books

edit

Journals

edit
edit