Talk:Tragedy of the commons/Archive 1
This is an archive of past discussions about Tragedy of the commons. Do not edit the contents of this page. If you wish to start a new discussion or revive an old one, please do so on the current talk page. |
Archive 1 | Archive 2 |
The "'invisible hand' (laissez-faire)" Statement is Improperly Used in the Article
The concept of the "invisible hand" and "laissez-faire" are both grounded in Lockean property rights, i.e., that so long as people's just property rights are for the most part respected that society takes care of itself, and that societal problems only occur when people's just property rights are violated (i.e., mostly by the government). Yet the article makes the false statement "As such, [the tragedy of the commons] illustrates how simplistic 'invisible hand' (laissez-faire) approaches to resource problems need not provide the expected optimal solution." The tragedy of the Tragedy of the Commons is that it lacks Lockean property rights.
I'm surprised that the liberal solution to this problem isn't even mentioned in the article. The Tragedy of the Commons is very often cited by libertarians as a classic example of what happens when people are not allowed to homestead resources (i.e., prohibited from doing so by the government).
To give one libertarian website's example, as of right now Google returns 181 pages with the phrase "tragedy of the commons" from Mises.org:
209.208.77.192 00:37, 11 March 2006 (UTC)
- If the solution you're talking about isn't mentioned in the article, please add it in the appropriate place - there's a section on "Possible solutions". As regards property rights, many of the examples given by Hardin in his original paper are difficult to resolve this way. For example, atmospheric pollution. Even now, many years after the Kyoto agreement, there's still very little resolved on this particular issue (though the Montreal Protocol on CFCs provides something of a counter-example). Cheers, --Plumbago 10:10, 12 March 2006 (UTC)
- For the libertarian solution to air pollution (grounded in the Lockean conception of property rights), see "Law, Property Rights, and Air Pollution," Murray N. Rothbard, Cato Journal, Vol. 2, No. 1 (Spring 1982), pp. 55-100 http://www.cato.org/pubs/journal/cj2n1/cj2n1-2.pdf . See also "Free-Market Environmentalism Reading List," The Commons Blog http://commonsblog.org/free_reading.php . 209.208.77.233 18:07, 13 March 2006 (UTC)
"By cooperating, every individual agrees not to seek more than its share. Defection happens when an individual realizes that it's in its interest to use more than its share of public property."
- I do not like that quote; it has an obvious flaw, being that it is not in his interest to take more than his share. Such an act would break the trust people have in him, thus making any cooperation, which is invariably benefical to every group, impossible with that individual. --Guizzy 00:32, 29 Sep 2004 (UTC)
These "its" sound really weird. Does Wikipedia have any usage/grammar guidelines we can refer to?
- You are right; its is only to be used if there is specifically no gender to the owner of the object, and not the gender is variable. In this case, the neutral masculine possessive form should be assumed to be the most appropriate.
- I wrote that. I'm portuguese, be free to correct me. Joao
I've fixed them. John Lynch
It looks that the expression "the tragedy of the commons" comes from Garrett Hardin's article "The Tragedy of the Commons," Garrett Hardin, Science, 162(1968):1243-1248. Quote from the article:
"The rebuttal to the invisible hand in population control is to be found in a scenario first sketched in a little-known Pamphlet in 1833 by a mathematical amateur named William Forster Lloyd (1794-1852). [6] We may well call it "the tragedy of the commons," using the word "tragedy" as the philosopher Whitehead used it [7]: "The essence of dramatic tragedy is not unhappiness. It resides in the solemnity of the remorseless working of things." He then goes on to say, "This inevitableness of destiny can only be illustrated in terms of human life by incidents which in fact involve unhappiness. For it is only by them that the futility of escape can be made evident in the drama.""
http://www.dieoff.org/page95.htm
My interpretation of this, is that mathematical amateur named William Forster Lloyd used the overexploitation of the commons as an example, but the expression was used by the first time by Hardin. Joao
- Hardin's essay is often mentioned by people who have perhaps never read it, and who might not agree with its thesis. I think it is appropriate to add parenthetically that the essay calls for coerced birth control to prevent human overpopulation. Will McW 00:01, 19 Oct 2004 (UTC)
The following text seemed very obscure to me, so I decided to put it here until someone can explain what it might mean...
Free software and colloborative projects like Wikipedia prove that for many digital commons the tragedy becomes a comedy.
- R Lowry 18:06, 22 Jun 2004 (UTC)
It means that collaborative projects are not affected by the so called Tragedy. --Guizzy 00:32, 29 Sep 2004 (UTC)
I believe it means the writer has an issue with Free software and/or collaborative projects. John Morgan 11 Apr 2008
cf 'Enclosure of the commons'
I've added the following text and link fairly up-front in the article by way of introduction and to broaden the terms of reference of the piece - which contextualises it and removes the charge of 'false history' somewhat. I personally find the real-world social conditions of the enclosure more interesting than game theory, and it is more connected to the observations of the UK property lawyer and others here... But apparently the 'enclosure' article needs cleaning up (I think it has a poor introduction that does not outline the case succinctly or quickly enough)--Sean01 08:38, 28 February 2006 (UTC)
- See also the related real-world event of the 'Enclosure of the commons', and its attendant social problems, which may have inspired the content of the parable.
Possible example to include
An example was just removed from the PD page which is claimed to actually be a 'tragedy' example. See Talk:Prisoner's_dilemma#Water_shortage:_Bad_example. I've copied the deleted text below in case it is appropriate for this article.
- Another example would be hoarding supplies of an essential item during a shortage. Let's say that all our tap water gets poisoned, somehow, and everyone has to rely on bottled water from supermarkets. Rationally, each person knows that they should limit their purchases of bottled water for the period of the shortage (ie, they should 'co-operate'), because if everybody rushes to the supermarket and stocks up on water (ie, if they 'defect') supplies will quickly run out — so that, in the long-run, there will be nothing left for anyone. However, each person also fears that hoarding is precisely what everybody else will be doing; therefore, rationally, they know that if they are to be sure of securing any supply of water at all they had better go and stock up too.
A note on the preceeding paragraph: The author suggests that if everyone rushed to stock up on water, then supplies will run out. I would have to argue that if prices are fully flexible, then prices will rise to a point where people will demand less of the good. We should not think that water is exaustible. Rather, at the current market price and the quantity demanded, producers will supply where demand and supply meet. When water prices rise, producers have the necessary funds to extract the water that has become more expensive. As long as prices rise enough to a point where it becomes viable to extract water, we should not worry about supplies running out.
- This scenario fits the PD payoff matrix outlined above: defection when others co-operate (T) means you can keep on getting a generous supply of drinking water repeatedly, because others are restricting their consumption; mutual co-operation (R) would bring the reward of a moderate amount of drinking water for everyone, over an extended period; mutual defection (P) would mean that everyone gets a lot to start off with but they probably all die of thirst soon enough thereafter; co-operation when others defect (S) means you end up with hardly any water, because it has all been snapped up by other people.
Wolfman 18:31, 6 Aug 2004 (UTC)
- Thanks for bringing this text over. As the original author of the above water shortage example, I was a little disappointed to see it removed from the Prisoner's dilemma article, tho' I didn't protest because I think the reason was a fair one. The second paragraph presumably wouldn't belong in this article, as it refers specifically to the PD payoff matrix, but I see nothing wrong with using the first paragraph here as a 'tragedy' example. However, since I obviously have an interest in saying that I'll wait for a few days before making the change, in case anyone comes up with any objections. R Lowry 19:18, 6 Aug 2004 (UTC)
- OK, it's done. R Lowry 20:41, 10 Aug 2004 (UTC)
- I disagree that this is a good example. The term "Tragedy of the Commons" was introduced for a situation where the overall amount of a usually replenishing resource is diminished by over-use (as also stated in the lead paragraph). No such thing occurs in the quoted water example; water is not lost but "only" distributed unfairly. That may be a tragedy, but does not fit here.
Historical Commons
Perhaps the article should contain some example of commons that didn't result in tragedy.
In the alpine region, most of the land (mainly forest and high pastures) was communally owned by a village or group of villages. Regulations kept under control the exploitation of the shared resource, although population has been for long time near the subsistence level.
See R. McC Netting "Balancing on a Alp"
On the other hand, there's the Easter Island case.
The defintion of "commoner" here, that it is a subset of the general public is at odds with commoner? -- PL 15/12 23:08
False history?
My problem with the historical part of this article is it doesn't match what little I know about the way that the law of commons worked (and of course works, because they still exist) in England and Wales.
Essentially there are two kinds of right. From memory about 10% of common rights are "at large" and amount to a right to put a fixed number of a particular kind of animal on the common. They were property and could be traded (contrary to what is said in the article).
Most rights were rights of "levancy and couchancy" -- the right to put animals of a particular type was attached to a plot of land. The number of animals you could overwinter on that land (hence "levancy and couchancy") was the number you could put on the common the rest of the year. The theory being that external factors would be taken into account so that you could put more animals on in a good year than a bad one. This right was, historically although not any more, attached to land and not "at large", though one could still say it was "property".
However in both cases the right to put animals on the common was limited. There was no "tragedy of the commons". The phrase being an example of the totally idiotic view that modern intellectuals have of the mediaevals, who were not stupid and would have been well aware of the problem of allowing too many animals on the common against the common good. Its like believeing that mediaeval people thought the world was flat -- it says more about the ignorance of modern people than of their predecessors.
PS: I am a English property lawyer, so I am quite sure about the law part of this.
Francis Davey 19:33, 18 Feb 2005 (UTC)
- Please, be bold and correct the text as you think best. The fact is that there are two stories here- the historical commons, and the metaphorical commons. The man who created the metaphor (at least in modern day), was not a property lawyer, he was an American scientist, and probably had a faulty view of how the commons worked. Cheers, -Willmcw 22:40, Feb 18, 2005 (UTC)
Actually, what I've been told is that the commons worked too well for individuals who joined the collective, which is why parliment had to enact enclosure laws, in order to dis-enfranchise people working their way up the ladder, and to be able to sell of the land to rich landowners to expand sheep production. In Scotland, they were *pissed*. Of course I don't have a ready source for that, but maybe that should be looked into.
Also, the 'tragedy of the commons' was a propoganda piece published to throw-off people who were against wholesale appropriation.
Kinda like 'survival of the fittest', which was from a political tract to justify takings from the whole of society, was grafted onto Darwin's evolutionary theory.
~ender 2003-04-14 02:52 MST
- If you are referring to Hardin's essay, "The Tragedy of The Commons", then you should know it has nothing to do with property or appropriations. The "commons" in that essay is the gene pool. Hardin is arguing against the ability of anyone to add to the population, and in favor of state-controlled reproduction. Cheers, -Willmcw 19:31, Apr 24, 2005 (UTC)
- "Gene pool" isn't in that essay.
- Using more recent terminology, one can argue that Hardin was concerned about the "meme pool"
- as persons who have the most children have more offspring to pass on their ideas of
- large families being attractive -- he's very clear on this point, he just didn't have the word "meme." ~Droper 19:12:12 MST 2006
- Hardin was a right-wing life-boat-ethic conservative lamenting
- the difficulty of enclosing -- placing property rights on -- the GLOBAL commons. He figured that pretty
- much all other commons had been and could be enclosed; hence, no tragedy for non-global commons
- according to Hardin.
- He's arguing for state control of reproduction precisely because the global commons
- can not be enclosed. W/o either enclosure of the global commons or state control of breeding
- the oceans and atmosphere get trashed. I have a ready source -- the article!
- plus pretty much everything else he wrote. Why can't we believe he meant what he wrote?
- Droper 18:24:02 MST 2006
- "Gene pool" isn't in that essay.
- Reread the concluding paragraphs. They include lines which say that the freedom to breed must be curtailed. In any case, we're trying to keep the discussions of the historical commons and Hardin's metaphoric commons separate in the article. -Will Beback 01:51, 2 March 2006 (UTC)
- Doesn't that beg the question of whether the primary thrust of his paper was a metaphor?
- As he says "the air and waters surrounding us cannot readily be fenced..." "Fenced" is a metaphor
- but I submit that the major application of his idea is a real world prediction.
- It is true that the title that others have taken as a metaphor refers to the simple argument of the
- working of the logic, viz., if you don't propertize (whether it's owned by the state or privately owned
- does not, as he makes clear, make a difference for his argument) the commons they will be ruined.
- Historically speaking he may have been in error to believe that all successful efforts to prevent 'over grazing' have been found in applying well-defined property rights. But he was only trying to explicate the logic of "the commons" before getting to the
- big application. His implication for the future was about the global commons
- -- it obviously turned out to be green house gases in both the oceans and atmosphere causing (in the opinion of many) a tragedy.
- Reread the concluding paragraphs. They include lines which say that the freedom to breed must be curtailed. In any case, we're trying to keep the discussions of the historical commons and Hardin's metaphoric commons separate in the article. -Will Beback 01:51, 2 March 2006 (UTC)
- However, if Hardin weren't just full of it, it would have been the most heavily populated countries that contributed the most to the accumulation of greenhouse gasses. This has turned out to be false. It is not the countries with the highest reproductive rates that have turned out to be the greatest burden. Likewise, his claim that education would be useless has also turned out to be false. Only one country has implemented the policies he suggested that would "protect" freedom and human rights, and it's a country with one of the worst records running on those two matters.
- It may be true that so many subsequent authors have used the title of his '68 paper as a metaphor that it's
- important to recognize this influence, but if we think Hardin is worthy of so much attention
- then don't we owe him the respect of taking his work more seriously, like perhaps he really meant what he
- said -- that since we can't "fence" the atmosphere and oceans and since we probably
- won't be able to coerce sufficiently low birth rates that the global commons will be trashed?
- It's not like I'm squeezing blood out of a turnip to get this "interpretation."
- Does this '68 article not contain one of the greatest falsifible predictions of social science
- now being (in the eyes of many) confirmed by global warming?
- Perhaps global warming is not happening or perhaps, even if it is, some other
- theory is about to supercede Hardin's. But don't we owe the guy credit for something more
- than articulating a metaphor?? Perhaps my remarks are more germane to the page on Hardin
- but that page links this page via the title "Tragedy of the Commons" and I came over
- here to find that his most famous paper is treated as (a long winded) metaphor.
- When Boulding (among others) gave us the metaphor "space ship earth" his original paper
- took about 3 pages, double spaced. I don't think anyone is intentionally underrating
- Hardin, but this page and the other "Hardin" page, taken together, seriously underrate
- his intellectual contribution, imo.
-Droper 19:28:16 MST 2006
- OTOH, it has been cited in many, many other contexts. This fact should be examined in the article. Mr. Jones 19:00, 4 May 2005 (UTC)
- That has not been a problem in the past. In fact, for a long time there was no reference to the actual content of the essay, and even now it is virtually a footnote. Hardin's metaphor is useful far beyond his intended purpose, a purpose that may embarrass some of those who quote it. -Willmcw 19:15, May 4, 2005 (UTC)
- OTOH, it has been cited in many, many other contexts. This fact should be examined in the article. Mr. Jones 19:00, 4 May 2005 (UTC)
- Got a link to that paper? I don't believe that was the information I was reading (but I'm willing to check). I was reading about sheep and enclosure laws specifically (ie: England ramping up production to dominate the trade).
- ~ender 2005-05-02 18:03:MST
Digital commons
Many people argue that the 'tragedy of the commons' principle does not apply to certain aspects of the digital world, because sharing information and software with other people does not decrease the amount that is available for others. Indeed, as the writer Eric S. Raymond, in an essay called The Magic Cauldron [2] has pointed out, in the case of open source software more widespread use actually tends to increase the usefulness of a product — the more people that are finding and correcting bugs, the better it is for everybody. Raymond has described this process as the inverse commons (see also: network effect). A similar process may be observed in collaborative, open content projects like the Wikipedia encyclopedia.
I'm not sure what this has to do with the digital world. Furthermore, it seems to be a strawman. Does anyone argue that the tragedy of the commons does occur in these situations? anthony (see warning) 01:00, 22 Aug 2004 (UTC)
- (William M. Connolley 21:05, 22 Aug 2004 (UTC)) I restored the para, but only because I objected to the gross language from POlyglut. But I don't understand your arguments against it: the connection to the digital world seems obvious.
- It seems to me that some misidentify copyright law as solving a tragedy of the commons. That's just not true in the first place. Copyright law is designed to resolve a free rider problem, not a tragedy of the commons. The difference, as is somewhat explained here, is that sharing information does not decrease the amount that is available for others. But like I said, that's really a strawman argument. Moreover, what I really don't understand is why this is somehow specific to the digital world. Whether digital or analog, sharing information doesn't decrease the amount that is available for others.
- --Kalclark 16:05, 6 December 2005 (UTC)Copyright law does solve a free rider problem but another one of its intents is to deal with a tragedy of the commons. If free access to a book was given then it would result in great benefit to the consumer and little benefit to the author, if access was determined by a mutual agreement on price (by the author and consumer), both achieve maximimal benefit. Copyright deals with the tragedy of the commons by allowing an invisible hand to control production and price and prevent a tragedy of the commons. The term free rider applies to agents who disrupt this balance, they are not isolated.
- The author would benefit from other free accessed books. The community at large would benefit greatly. People who can't afford buying books benefits etc etc. I don't see how this would be a tragedy. (there is a lot of means for income)
- Of course, maybe this isn't about copyright law in the first place. I'm kind of guessing, but copyright law isn't even mentioned here.
- And, of course, the tragedy of the commons does occur in the digital world, in areas other than that of information. For instance, spam has caused a tragedy of the commons with regard to email.
- --Kalclark 16:05, 6 December 2005 (UTC)Spam does cause a tragedy of commons because email is a means of communication. Right now we have an endless ability to transfer information because of a large amount of bandwidth. As societies continue to increase the access to the public bandwidth through hi-speed, public hi-speed, corporate hi-speed, and next-gen hi-speed the public good (bandwidth) will be degraded. Even now, many people have bandwidth caps on their personal machines. However, as access to resource becomes scarce, prices increase, drawing more suppliers to the market, resulting in less scarcity. We're all okay.
- Finally, I figured your restoration of the comment was more due to the way in which Polyglut removed the text. But that paragraph was already one which was bothering me, and after looking at it again I'm just not convinced it should stay, at least not without being clarified. anthony (see warning) 21:51, 22 Aug 2004 (UTC)
- (William M. Connolley 22:05, 22 Aug 2004 (UTC)) I don't understand why you have introduced copyright. But I'm not desperately happy with the para either.
- Open source, open content, these are terms which are related to copyright. anthony (see warning) 22:42, 22 Aug 2004 (UTC)
-- i added the following comment:
<<the digital commons, are properganda of the wikipedian fuckfaces, as usual. basically, you'll see such in any article these OpenSourcers can remotely insert their shit. Xah Xah Lee 15:01, 2004 Aug 22 (UTC)>>
and it got deleted by Anthony DiPierro. Since when do OpenSource fuckfaces not only insert properganda into articles and delete opposing edits, and now censor arguments in the discussion section? Is it because it contain swearing, fuckfaces? Xah Lee 23:04, 2004 Aug 24 (UTC)
- (William M. Connolley 09:11, 25 Aug 2004 (UTC)) You'll generally find swearing counterproductive, as it is in this case. Being able to spell propaganda would help, too.
- I didn't find anything useful in your comment, but if you choose to readd it I won't fight with you about it. By the way, you might want to note that I'm the one arguing for the deletion of this content, not the one adding it. In fact, as there doesn't appear to be anyone arguing for inclusion, and I can't think of a way to distill this down into something appropriate for Wikipedia (NPOV, verifiable, not original research, related to the topic), I'm going to delete it now and see what happens. As for the profanity, we do have a rule against unnecessary profanity, (Wikipedia:Profanity), as well as one against personal attacks (Wikipedia:No personal attacks). anthony (see warning) 11:56, 25 Aug 2004 (UTC)
-- An argument in favor of "Open Source or Open information" paragraph:
The idea of open sharing of resources is always looked upon with some distrust by humans. And not without good reasons: the "Tragedy of the Commons" is a vivid illustration of some of these reasons. Given that context, it seems nice to point to a domain where these reasons do not apply very strongly. Forms a nice counterpoint. As remarked by another poster, it can be put in terms of "information sharing" with Open Source software only as an example.
- I totally agree that it should be mentioned since it _is_ common.
- Hardin himself drew attention to the distinction of sharing information rather than materials or energy. There's a chapter in his book Filters Against Folly (chapter 12, pp. 170-183), that deals specifically with this issue. You might find it interesting if you can track down a copy of this book. Cheers, --Plumbago 09:55, 23 February 2006 (UTC)
Property and tradeability
Since I last edited any of this, someone has altered it based on a US-centric misundersting of property. For the record, the property article contains this: "Property is defined as the right to use, enjoy or possess a determinant thing, and the right to exclude others from doing the same." This does not require tradeability; in fact, the second part is merely an implication of the first.
Property implies tradeability if, and only if, the thing in question can only be enjoyed by being traded, the way you don't get any benefit from money if you can't spend it.
- quibble: You can get value from money, for example you can use paper fiat money as notepaper, wallpaper (post WWI Germany comes to mind), insulation, tinder for fires, in stacks as blocks for children to play with, and as toliet paper. Coinage can be melted down, etc.
- Non-fiat money can be redeemed for its equivalent - historically gold or silver - both of which have non-monetary value.
- Of course if you meant you can't get near the benefits from money's reputed value if you can't spend it, I'll agree. But be careful with your statements.
- ~ender 2005-05-20 02:13:MST
On the other hand, there are many forms of property that need not be tradeable to be capable of being enjoyed; land is one such. The idea that you can only fully own land as property if you can trade it is US-centric, from the very things the USA put in on purpose like banning entails of land. Yet under other systems, entailed land - despite not being tradeable - was most definitely property. And of course, under the mandate Zionists placed restrictions on the sale of land they bought so that it would remain forever within the settler community and could not return to Palestinians once they were no longer so poor, a sort of ratchet. The thing is, certain restrictions can actually enhance the ability to enjoy and actually increase the ownership.
The long and the short of all this is, whoever edited this to assert that commoners' rights weren't property because they weren't tradeable was plain wrong. It's only property that is essentially liquid, inherently needing value in trade like money, that needs to be tradeable to be property. But commoners' rights had value in use. PML.
- (William M. Connolley 08:34, 22 Sep 2004 (UTC)) I disagree with you. And I'm not from the US. So I've restored it. Your examples are poor: land is tradeable. As for your quote from wiki: read a bit further down.
- (William M. Connolley 15:27, 22 Sep 2004 (UTC)) I partly agree. I accept there is ambiguity though. Perhaps rather than stating whether or not the rights were property we simply state that they could not be sold? As to fee tail land: I accept it could not be traded. But its not really clear that it was property in that case.
- As I explain above (under the historical section) rights of common certainly could be sold, but most such rights were attached to land, so they could not be traded independantly of the land to which they were fixed, but since that could be sold (at least since Quia Emptores) they were something that could be exchanged for money value. Obviously one could also hire out their use. Francis Davey 00:59, 19 Feb 2005 (UTC)
- I originally put in the bundle of rights/property part, then someone US centric "corrected" it. I've now tried to separate out the issues, without resolving the part about being attached to the land (which I knew, but didn't emphasise). I believe that I covered how these rights could be leased (it was actually called "thistle rents"). That still leaves unresolved just how the rights could be sold, but I don't think we need to get into that detail in this article provided we only make it clear that where these things applied they really were property rights. At least, I hope nobody is so US-centric to dispute that other approaches exist, and US ones shouldn't be used when they weren't the relevant ones. It's like "Oh, you were married by the law of the country? but they don't have churches so you weren't really married, were you?"
- I'd also like to see all these "a commons" things cleared up, not just for pedantry but because it confuses the fact that there were lots of distinct commons, each somewhat different, and not conferring any general access to the public. The whole Prisoner's dilemma thing comes from a difference between "each" and "all", and that makes this mechanism sensitive to what is singular and what is plural - it isn't a quibble, the way objecting to the Americanism "a woods" would be. PML.
Digital Commons isn't a tragedy of the commons because the digital commons are, for all intents and purposes, unlimited. The tragedy of the commons only applies where there is unlimited demand, which can be satisfied without cost, for a limited resource. the digital common is not a limited resource. ElectricRay 22:47, 31 August 2006 (UTC)
Papers that cite this one
There must be very many! However, I wonder if there are any we could refer to that describe the effect of selfish groups (rather than individuals) on the common good. Famous papers that refer to it would be good to mention too. Anyone have access to a citation index? Mr. Jones 18:20, 4 May 2005 (UTC)
Nations
- For example, although most commons are regulated locally in the form of emissions standards, land use zoning and the like, the international community has not instituted regulations for global commons such as the ozone layer, oceans or polar icecaps, thus allowing primarily industrialized nations to overtax these resources without penalty.
This text overwrote some existing text on experimental findings about behavior. It's not bad, but it was in the wrong place. Can anyone see a good way to work it in? -Willmcw 05:31, July 22, 2005 (UTC)
Structure
The article has a rather large opening section before the index. It might make more sense to have a single introductory paragraph (basically the first one already there), then shove the rest of the text (which actually describes the tragedy) into its own section in the body of the article. I'd do this without asking (as it's only a structural consideration), but I notice that the article's been cited by the press. Does this mean I should be extra careful or something? Cheers, --Plumbago 13:13, 22 August 2005 (UTC)
- That's fine. The fact that it's been cited is an honor, but it shouldn't stop us from improving the article further. Cheers, -Willmcw 21:19, August 22, 2005 (UTC)
Hypothesis outline
Just a couple of points :
- Hardin doesn't mention the English Commons in his original essay. He uses the example of a common grazing pasture as his Commons, but it's certainly not specified in relation to some particular historical example (so the section on history is a bit redundant; although it's possible that Hardin mistakenly brought in this historical example in a later article I've not read).
- Although it's not mentioned directly in the article right now, he goes on in his original essay to discuss examples including pollution, human populations, National Parks, overfishing and even car parking. People often get stuck on the idea of pastures and cows in relation to the tragedy.
- Another thing missing from this article is that right from the start of Hardin's essay he makes the point that there are no technical solutions to the tragedy. This is where the "mutual coercion mutually agreed upon" concept comes in. It also marks the essay out as rare in scientific literature since it deals explicitly with morality, and not simply objective science.
Anyway, will try to address these points if no-one objects. --Plumbago 07:55, 23 August 2005 (UTC)
- I'm certainly in favor of keeping this this article grounded in adiscussion of Hardin's essay. It's better to add information than to remove it. Cheers, -Willmcw 10:11, August 23, 2005 (UTC)
Communism and Polder Model
I'm surprised that there is no mention of communism in the article. Communism assumes the 'goodness of man' (or how should I put it?) and without that you get this. Another phenomenon that is interresting in this respect is the polder model, which might also be worthy of a mention. See also the talk page there. DirkvdM 08:54, 15 September 2005 (UTC)
- In the first instance, it might be interesting to know what the polder model actually is. The article on it doesn't actually say at the moment, it just alludes to it being a type of management without clarifying what that management is. It would be good to know how this example of a commons is managed (but by all means add the example of polders to the list of commons on this article's page).
- As regards communism (and other "solutions" to the tragedy), I think that the article requires some editing so that there's a specific section on escape from the tragedy. I've been meaning to do this for a while (see entry above), but will try to get my skates on. --Plumbago 09:35, 15 September 2005 (UTC)
- I'll add the Polder Model to the 'see also' section. I'm not sufficiently 'into this subject' do do much else. I just wanted to make a suggestion. DirkvdM 09:08, 16 September 2005 (UTC)
I think the Polder Model is not so much a way of solving the problem as a procedural recommendation for dealing with it. My understanding comes from 4 years of living in the Netherlands, but I suspect that this also resembles the Medieval methods used to determine individual rights on open meadows in England. The basic idea is that everyone with a stake, or perceived stake, in building, maintaining or changing a dike should be granted equal rights in the decision-making process. The decisions should be made in a sort of quasi-consensus precess: the final result will be the outcome of a committee, the committee should represent all the points of view present, and all members of the committee must be given equal time and their arguments considered equally. (A polder is a field created by reclaiming land from the sea through building dikes and draining.) The process is slow, but if you include enough different viewpoints from the beginning, there are very few major complaints at the end. It also avoids the type of mistakes brought on by 'group think'. suz 15:15, 6 December 2006 (UTC)
Stupidly biased articles
Could you people please refrain from inserting highly partisan language into your writing? It's annoying to read one IP/property article after another that is clearly written from an anti-property-rights, anti-capitalist perspective.
The tragedy of the commons is an economic theory. To say it's based on a misunderstanding of evidence is nonsensical. Perhaps it was motivated by a misunderstanding of evidence. If that is the case, you should write, "Some sociological evidences calls into question..."
I also want to point out that the Tragedy of Commons is a widely-accepted theory among property-law scholars. This article makes it sound like the theory is widely accepted to be false.
--Rmalloy 13:00, 19 September 2005 (UTC)
- agree with Rmalloy. this is a widely accepted theory. Anlace 23:02, 16 January 2007 (UTC)
I don't know how often I get the "widely-accepted" as an argument in a discussion. It is a down right stupid argument and if we were to accept it then the earth would be flat. As for the article it is important to keep the "widely accepted" bias on as it is the purpuse of an encyclopedia, and I agree to the point of the comment. But ...
It is difficult to discuss the whole notion of "tragedy of commons" without a bias as it is a biased theory at it's best. There is a mechanism that does brings fourth short sightedness in all of us but it has nothing to do with commons. It has to do with arbitrage and ability to utilize the arbitrage. In this case you need to understand (or imagine, depending on what you choose to beleave) that there is a similar exchange between the market of today and market of tomorrow as there is between two markets that are separated by location or concept.
For any individual there is an opportunity to sell the commodity today or tomorrow. If he perceives the price (ie. not ammount of money but amount of good perceived) of the commodity equal or better today he will sell it in any other case he will wait until tomorrow (if not forced by necessities). Any such earning by transfering goods from one market to another without an actual risk is called arbitrage, and market mechanisms will remove any such earning by setting a new equilibrium removing the arbitrage.
Now the "Tragedy of Commons" argues that: "a single owner of a resource in not having to compete for it, is perfectly motivated to preserve it in a way that unregulated communal owners are not" (atleast from what I read from the article - and if it doesn't, then it is poorly written).
Lets take one relatively old example. A family knows a secret recepie for headache medicine. They do not have to compete and are therefore perfectly motivated to preserve the commodity for future generations. Now they are presented with an option. They can continue with the preservation of the resource, or to disclose the secret, but by disclosing it they will be granted exclusive rights to sell the commodity for a limited ammount of time. Given that they have no motivation to compete they simply should not do it, even so historically we know that it has happened.
As far as my scientific reasoning goes this should atleast serve as a plausible evidence that the categorical statement possibly could be untrue. And thus we could move to a less categorical statement. that a communal resource is less likely to be preserved than a private one. In accepting that the diffference between communal and private is only size of probability, I'd argue that the relationshipt is highly casual.
In discussion when given examples of how private ownership leads to the same result as communal ownership I always encounter the same reaction. We start to make up "regulations" of why "this" example of private ownership actually is an exception, and why it doesn't count. Nobody makes up these excuses for the communal, as the theory so well fits our perception of ownhership and our intuitive models of human nature.
I'd argue that in every case where anyone is given an opportunity for arbitrage by depleeting a resource it will be done, independent of his relation to the resource, private ownership, comunal ownership or even stolen.
One of our most common resrouces today are brand names. Even if most of the brand names are privately owned, given the choice of perserving the brand name for the future or maximizing the the short term revenue (ie. depleeting the resource), they will always choose depleetion over preservation.
In the founding examples of "tragedy of commons" there is one major fact that is left out, and it is the ability to see the arbitrage. It is so simple just to grab a part of that commons and turn it into money. What is most important is that the arbitrage does not dissapear as future generations can't put a bid on the commodity changing the equilibrium price of the commons so that the arbitrage dissapears.
It might be that there is a difference in how fast things will be utilized with communal ownerhip and private, but then it is just a question of entry barriers.
Now to the final argument. It is possible that there exists a mechanism such as "tragedy of commons", but as long as nobody thoroughly looks at the underlaying mechanisms and accepts that the "tragedy of the privates" also exists, I find it more likely that it simply is a casual relation and therefore a myth. I admit a persuasvie such, buth still just a myth, and as such it removes focus from what is a necesary solution "regulations" to what isn't a solution "privatisation".
I'd look for following underlying causes. 1. Possibility for arbitrage. 2. Visibiltiy of arbitrage. 3. Relative wealth of owner. 4. Entry barriers to the opportunity to utilize a resrouce
and if I was certain of this ... well then I would post in the article instead of discussions. —The preceding unsigned comment was added by 137.61.234.225 (talk • contribs).
- unsigned posts dont really add very much. but i take strong exception to all the OR above. the person should write a book on the topic, but this is the place to talk objectively about the best way (with specifics) to write the wikipedia article. Anlace 23:05, 16 January 2007 (UTC)
- 137.61.234.225 - If you have notable sources who discuss the thesis that yo describe above then we can include it in this article. We're just reporting on what others have said, we're not engaged in finding the truth of the concept. -Will Beback · † · 22:52, 16 January 2007 (UTC)
I did an edit yesterday trying to replace what I wrote with a more targeted explanation claiming that the bias of the article is because the historical part isn't separated from the scientific, but it seems like I still have to learn about wikipedia as I can't see this change anywhere.
Anyhow after this I decided to check to see how some other article with a historical and scientific perspective was written and brought forth the article of "pythagoras theorem". It actually does start with a historical recollection and then goes forth to a scientific such.
After reading the discussion pages over and over again, I find it highly likely that the article fails add resent development in the field which further adds to the bias. Game Theory actually does explain that there is an underlaying theory that explains the mechanism, and that the "tragedy" just is one special case of outcome of the game. It is evident (at least to me, and I am a moron) that the common missperception that "tragedy of commons" is an argument for private ownership will be less persuasive by letting game theory be part of the scientific reasoning.
As far as I can read from game theory, it actually shows that those "widely-accepted" theories about tragedy of commons aren't so "widely-accepted". Game theory explains the same process, but it's far more neutral on effects of "ownership". Game theory also allows to reason around other cases where the individual acts with a short term interest, wich tragedy of commons does not.
I might not have been clear (I'm not a good writer), but it is how the article is written that bugs me, not the content. I am fairly sure that the "tragdedy of comons" is a legit observation as described in the article. I am more concerned of how many who read the article perceive it argruing for private ownership, which probably results in "highly partisan language" comments. The article could be written far more neutral (see the pythagoras-theoreme article) without loosing any of the "widely-accepted" parts.
83.250.193.139 11:59, 20 January 2007 (UTC)Yoki - who was lazy enough not to check how to sign.
- I don't know the topic but, for what it is worth, I agree. I think there is a biased tone in the article. The edits made 03:59, 8 June 2005 and 03:33, 8 June 2005 adds to the Introduction "misunderstood", "poor understanding" and "misunderstanding", on Hardin's part. The same edits also, in my opinion, disrupts the flow of the text between "any given situation" and "Experiments have indicated". I do not dare to fix anything myself.
- In External Links And References, there is a vague reference to a documentary "on cable TV". What day? What program title? What channel? What country? I think it can be removed. (David Andersson, 29 Sep 2005)
- I deleted the documentary non-link. However the matter of the difference between Hardin's view of how a commons worked and the the way that real commons worked is important to keep repeating. This article is on his theory, not the real commons, but it's important to show that his analogy is flawed, even though his conclusion is worthwhile. -Willmcw 19:54, 29 September 2005 (UTC)
- Respectfully disagree entirely I'm afraid Willmcw. I know I've said it already (and not done anything about it), but Hardin was not interested in real pastures. So examples of how real pastures (with cows) may be managed, while interesting (and worth retaining in the article), do not invalidate his point. His real interest mostly lay with things that are often not even recognised as commons, and so aren't managed at all (i.e. they conform to his open access pasture). Things like the atmosphere and ocean, or resources like freshwater and fishstocks. As he states in his original essay, his primary preoccupation is with unrestricted human population growth, and one of his lifelong hobby horses was how the management of this, or even the discussion of it, was a taboo (and taboos effectively abolish management). Anyway, I'm wittering on and not improving the article. I will try to do so soon. Honest. (A failure to manage the commons of my own free time ...) --Plumbago 21:52, 29 September 2005 (UTC)
- Er, that's part of the point. Hardin seemed to believe incorrectly that the commons were unmanaged, and built his metaphor on that basis. And no, he wasn't talking about things like the oceans, fishstocks, or the atmosphere. He was talking about reproductive rights to the human gene pool and the earth's carrying capacity of humans. I strongly suggest that you read his article (its short) before improving this one. Thanks, -Willmcw 21:59, 29 September 2005 (UTC)
- Again, respectful disagreement. For one thing, some of the examples that he mentions in his paper (fishstocks, atmosphere, oceans, rivers; see pages 1245 and 1248) either remain as commons (e.g. the atmosphere; though even here there are weak agreements like Kyoto), are ineffectively managed commons (e.g. oceanic fishstocks) or only managed where it is easy to do so (e.g. rivers). There are a couple of paragraphs on the final page (1248) where he discusses abandonment of commons (in the unmanaged sense) for managed systems. The pastures-as-commons is introduced as an analogy (on page 1244 only), which I don't think is fleshed out with an explicit example in the original paper (although I'm aware that he returned to it in later work with a specific example of grazing lands in Africa). As regards population, I did say in my previous post above that this was his primary preoccupation in the essay (it's even the subtitle of the paper). It dominates the original paper in terms of word count, and though Hardin's interests are much broader than just this, it is a common (if you pardon the expression) theme of much of his work. With respect to the article at hand, I think much of it is fine, although I can see why there's some protest about its POV status. Don't worry though, I won't be setting fire to it or anything. :) Cheers, --Plumbago 08:35, 30 September 2005 (UTC)
- OK, I trust you. Go for it. Cheers, -Willmcw 14:24, 30 September 2005 (UTC)
- Hello again. Right, I've made changes to the bulk of the article. It still needs work on the "solutions" section, although I think this was less of a cause for the above consternation. I've tried to give a full description of the original essay, including reference to its scope and content. I've changed the tone of the "controversy" section to better reflect things as I understand them. Please feel free to disagree. I've tidied up the bit on the history of real "commons" so that it doesn't mistake Hardin's hypothetical example for the real deal. And I've marginally tidied the modern commons section, but I think the list can be rationalised further.
- As regards the article's neutrality status, I've tried to contact Rmalloy both via his/her talk page and by e-mail. However, I've not heard anything back (nor has Rmalloy made any edits since September). Rather than wait indefinitely, I'll remove the neutrality warning at the head of the article tomorrow, unless anyone objects that is. From the above comments, I think the cause of the original debate has been resolved. Your mileage may vary.
- I hope my changes have improved the article. Cheers, --Plumbago 12:56, 2 November 2005 (UTC)
- Good work. Thanks for giving the article your careful attention. Cheers, -Willmcw 19:39, 2 November 2005 (UTC)
- Cool. Thanks for reading it. I'll remove the neutrality notice from the article. Hopefully there'll be more comments from Rmalloy at some point. Cheers, --Plumbago 13:42, 3 November 2005 (UTC)
Light pollution
I'm pulling this from the list of modern commons because it's not as clear a case as other examples. While light "pollutes" the sky and obscures the stars for everyone, the light sources that do so usually provide a public benefit as well (e.g. illuminating objects you'd rather not bump in to). The are exceptions, but on the whole lighting things up conveys benefit. A good contrast is with noise pollution. While there are examples of where this conveys benefit (e.g. police/fire/ambulance sirens), on the whole noise added to the environment is clearly pollution. --Plumbago 13:07, 2 November 2005 (UTC)
No, this is a good example, but the point is that its not light but stray light that should be considered. This is perhaps an example of 'inverted tragedy of the commons'? It takes only a little effort on one persons part to prevent stray light spoiling the night sky for everyone, but no one has any incentive to bother, because their lone effort will not be seen to make any difference, so they will not gain in praise or status. --Lindosland 21:08, 24 December 2005 (UTC)
- agree with Lindosland. Anlace 22:58, 16 January 2007 (UTC)
Isn't?-
Isn't "Tragedy of The Commons" about At least one person in a collective screwing things up for the rest by not making use of the available resource properly, ie, within the rules and regulations as set by the group to protect the group from, for instance, vandalism, over consumption, disorderly conduct, et al? Michael 14:31, 3 November 2005 (UTC)
- Strictly speaking, the commons of Hardin's essay are unmanaged (i.e. free-for-all), while a collective provides a form of resource management (which may or may not be successful). Hardin does discuss the failings of management by conscience, which is, I guess, how some collectives are managed, but his point isn't directed specifically at collectives (at least in his original essay). --Plumbago 17:47, 3 November 2005 (UTC)
Evolutionary psychology has studied the concept in detail, independantly of Hardin's observations. To them the phrase 'the tragedy of the commons' has been adopted to refer to what tends to happen in the absence of laws, conscience, penalties etc. For a long time evolutionists argued that altruism could not have evolved through 'group selection' because selfish individuals in the group would always do best and hence come to have more offspring - resulting in a more selfish group. Some argued for 'inclusive fitness' as an answer to this problem, claiming that we help relatives only to help our own shared genes to spread. Many now reject that explanation, but see the tragedy of the commons (as an emergent self-evident property of nature) as the very reason why laws evolved as part of every society - to make sure that the selfish individual doesn't get to win! --Lindosland 21:21, 24 December 2005 (UTC)
Modern commons
This list of potential "modern commons" appears to be mostly original research. I'm inlined to think we should cut down the list to items which have been notably called "modern commons", rather than those items which we, the Wikipedia editors, think belong. -Willmcw 01:06, 7 November 2005 (UTC)
I don't agree since I came to know the phrase through the rapidly growing field of Evolutionary Psychology. The 'tragedy of the commons' is looking like a fundamental 'law' of nature: an 'emergent property' of 'complex systems' with many many consequences that have long been around but are only just being seen as a result of this phenomenon. Forget old and new, this is much bigger than was ever imagined when the phrase came into being.
I see for example that my 'competition for loudness' relating to CD's and Radio has been moved down as being a 'minor tragedy'. As an expert in quality measurement I have to say that many engineers recognise such competition as having made the concept of high-fidelity a pointless endeavour, a very real tragedy to those of us who have dedicated a large part of our lives to seeking ever better reproduction. While the early CD's of the 1980's took advantage of the wide dynamic range of digital sound, modern CD's all use compression to make them sound loud compared to others, with appalling loss of fidelity. If all producers agreed to make all CD' quieter, there would be room for the brief loud peaks that are necessary to give sparkle to recordings. As it is, non will be the first to turn down the volume. This may not be a tragedy in the grand scheme of life and death, but when you look at the role of digital audio in the modern world of the i-pod etc, its pretty big. More relevant by far now, I suggest, than 'poaching'! -- Lindosland 21:01, 24 December 2005 (UTC)
- Sorry, but compared to the collapse of fisheries, the destruction of forests, and overpopulation, the loss of fiedlity in music recordings is indeed a "minor" tragedy. Poaching of endangered species is an extremely serious matter. -Willmcw 21:06, 24 December 2005 (UTC)
Yes, Willmcw, as a man who grows organic food and loves his cod and chips I have to agree with you! Though I'm happy to go bottom of the list I think we should not try to list things in order of 'Tragedy' and I've just worked hard at a new introduction warning against a too literal an interpretation of the phrase. Re-reading the original article I found support for this which I was able to quote. The more examples the better, I suggest. They are either examples of this imorptant phenomenon or they are not. I've also taken out 'analogy' and put in 'metaphor' after careful consideration.
- I disagree with your view that "the more examples the better", unless they are examples for which we have sources. Otherwise we are engaging in original research. I agree that "metaphor" is a better description. -Willmcw 19:38, 26 December 2005 (UTC)
I'm not sure that identifying examples is 'original research' but I accept the need for caution, especially as there are subtle distinctions between cases that deplete a resource, cases that spoil a resource, and cases that unfairly distribute a resource. Maybe later we could expand each example with a short paragraph explaining how it qualifies as an example, or even distinguish apparent examples that ae questionable.
Metaphor is not just about better description: I was troubled by the grammar. I think an analogy has to be a complete description of something - a sentence at minimum. 'The tragedy of the commons' is a noun phrase, no verb, no description. Things like that trouble me! Like metaphor vs simile!
I can see why you moved the 'official article to the top', but I was finding it confusing to access quickly (tiny pdf box etc to click on), compared to the version I came across on the Hardin page which is nicely presented at one-click. Maybe both? --Lindosland 01:33, 27 December 2005 (UTC)
Could someone clarify to me how 'Uncontrolled human population growth' is a 'Tragedy of the commons' or a 'modern commons'? I completely understand how it can lead to environmental destruction, even collapse (see Easter Island), but what is the 'common' involved? For comparison consider the shared grazing grounds no one is responsible for, and thus gets overgrazed until it is just a muddy field...here the grazing grounds are the commons, and their destruction is the tragedy. I'm not sure how to package uncontrolled population growth into something similar. Any ideas?--Kaze0010 09:55, 28 June 2006 (UTC)
- Earth is the commons? Individually we benefit (however one wants to define this) from having children, but the Earth is degraded as a consequence. No-one's responsible for the Earth, hence the tragedy. The example of the pasture is actually pretty pertinent to human population growth since, as the article already points out, it deals with adding extra animals to a finite resource. Does that help? --Plumbago 10:37, 28 June 2006 (UTC)
- Yes, thank you. (The original wording just didn't work for me.) --Kaze0010 06:32, 29 June 2006 (UTC)
Introduction
I go away a few days, and look what happens ... ;) I think the introduction is far, far too long. The new text is interesting, but detracts I think because of its positioning. It would make more sense (to my mind) if it were moved below the section on the essay, as it's commentary on that.
As an aside, I think the portion about emergent phenomena is a bit too strong. If we're to call the TotC an "emergent phenomenon" and put stuff on the page about it, we'd be putting it onto thousands of pages. I don't believe it's a good enough example to merit a mention in this context.
One last thing, there's perhaps too much on evolutionary psychology I think. As a field it certainly doesn't have a monopoly on TotC, but it merits a note. Probably change the focus more towards game theory instead though.
Anyway, I'm really pleased the article's attracting more attention. Hope to contribute properly when I get back from my hols.
--Plumbago 10:43, 27 December 2005 (UTC)
- Plumbago: I did worry that I was making the introduction a bit long, and I was a bit wary of to going in at the top of a fairly mature article, but I'm pleased you find the material interesting. I tried very hard to make it as concise as possible.
In defence of what I've done, I was surprised on first coming to this article by the way people were analysing the words, almost as you might a literary effort, rather than catching on to the profound significance of the phenomenon. Evolutionary psychology is only one of my passions, but I do consider it a 'hot topic' at the moment, along with genetics, neuroscience, psychology and evolution. These are the areas that are rapidly answering our questions about life, while games theory seems to me to be in the background, in a supporting role like all maths.
The summary of the orginal article is good, but takes a bit of commitment to read through. I felt that the intro should tell new readers what the key idea is, and why it is important, and take them to other pages that might throw light on it. Its important because is shows us a 'self evident' reason for much that we see in life and in human behaviour. This fascinates me, because it goes to the core of what 'science' is supposed to be about but isn't. The TotC, like evolutionary selection, is not 'empirically determined', a 'law' to be tested by experiment, its just obvious once you see it (as Huxley commented to Darwin) (hence the games theory link). I think all science might be ultimately founded on such things (as Einstein did), and the current definition of science a bit of fudge. That makes the link to evolutionary psychology important. One thing Wiki does is take us from page to page. As it stood it just took them to Hardin and his idea. I think it better to take them to other pages where they can explore why the idea is so interesting.
Emergent phenomenon? Again its not one of those things you test by how many people think so. The idea that it MIGHT be seems worth a few words, thought provoking but hardly subversive, and a good link to another interesting page. --Lindosland 13:43, 27 December 2005 (UTC)
This article is about two things!
I think there is a major problem with this article as it stands, in that it is tackling two things: the phenomenon 'The Tragedy of the Commons' and what Hardin said in his article 'The Tragedy of the Commons'. This has led contributors to judge entries according to 'what Hardin said', and in particular with reference to what he suggested. It seems to me that his suggestions have a place in an article about Hardin and his work, but must not be used to judge what goes on this page.
'The Origin of Species' is not about what Darwin said, it's an ongoing topic. 'Darwinian Evolution' is not what Darwin said (he was largely Lamarkian), and no one with our current knowledge of evolution would look for truths by reference to Darwins writings.
Similarly, 'Tragedy of the Commons' is a phenomenon, and I'm not sure Hardin was even the first to refer to it. He certainly warrants credit here, but his article is surely of secondary importance to the phenomenon. I think we should attempt clearly distinguish between the two topics, or maybe split off Hardin's article to its own page. I certainly think there is room here for more analysis of current thinking on the phenomenon, and less emphasis on what Hardin said. --Lindosland 13:40, 28 December 2005 (UTC)
Having established that Hardin did not coin the phrase, or claim to, I have made changes in line with the above comments. The 'controversy' section is now simply misguided, but I've left it, pending a better one. --Lindosland 14:16, 28 December 2005 (UTC)
Controversy now makes sense, with the addition of 'Hardin's essay'. --Lindosland 14:49, 28 December 2005 (UTC)
'change of heart'
.......the real 'tragedy of the commons' is that in many cases it isn't talked about, overused or exploited any more at all, the real tragedy is that so often the commons are ignored! ....a few years back I helped a friend in the north of Aotearoa (New Zealand), a little place called Paihia. Every morning I would get Cup early and take Zar, my Boarder Collie, for a walk down to the beach and to watch the sun rise over the waters. That walk took us past the original commons, a small area of green next to the old church. Now, if you're lucky, you can spot a few people sunbathing on these greens but most people haven't got a clue about it's historical significance, don't use or enjoy it, ignore it. .........on my daily wanderings on the beach I couldn't help but notice all sorts of rubbish people left everywhere but in the designated bins. I picked away at it now and then and one day thought:'if this was my beach, I'd have it pristeenly clean.' That's when I realised that this was my beach. At ten to six in the morning I very rarely met anyone else there, I loved it and cared for it. It couldn't have been any more mine in all its spinetingling beauty than it already was. Cleaning up on my walks from there on, more than before that realisation, I soon noticed a marked improvement and barely any rubbish bar in the bins. I also noticed on some of my longer walks that I wasn't the only person anymore that took pride and action and within some weeks it was heaven every morning to say hi to the sun lazily rising above the waters of my clean beach...........
- I agree, and often do my bit on the beach at Aldeburgh in the same way. Some people here have suggested limiting the examples, leaving out more obscure ones, but I think if more people were aware of the phrase and its relevance to so many everyday things, they might wake up in the way that you did. --Lindosland 11:55, 7 January 2006 (UTC)
- We shold add all the sourced examples we can find. We should not make up or decide on examples ourselves, as that is original research. -Will Beback 19:37, 8 January 2006 (UTC)
Parable?
Is Tragedy of the Commons really a parable? Or is it a though experiment. Or an analogy? Or a problem? A parable is based on something readers know to be true. A reed does bend in wind and seeds sown upon rocks will. in fact not sprout. Moving one more animal into a pasture is not as obvious. Second I am unsure about the examples. The gambling, is that an example of T of the C? Or is it more of a case of the market becoming saturated at some point? And the social problems caused are just a negative eternality. And littering? Isn't that just pollution? Then logging of forests. Both logging and fishing can be at or below sustainable levels or above them. Fishing above sustainable levels is called overfishing. Overlogging is not a common term. What about sprawl? Each person moves out to the country for peace and tranquility, minimum traffic etc. Each one that move out lessens what the moved for until all open space is gone. Is that not tragedy of the commons? KAM 22:33, 15 May 2006 (UTC)
- The OED says that a parable is "An allegorical or metaphorical saying or narrative; an allegory, a fable, an apologue; a comparison, a similitude. Also: a proverb, a maxim; an enigmatic or mystical saying (now arch.)"; "A (usually realistic) story or narrative told to convey a moral or spiritual lesson or insight; esp. one told by Jesus in the Gospels. (Now the usual sense)". Rather broad I think you'll agree. And not strictly "based on something readers know to be true". I think "metaphor" or even "idealised model" covers it quite well. Basically, it's a straightforward outline of a resource allocation problem couched in a setting that most readers will easily picture and so easily understand the lessons drawn from it.
- As for the examples in the article, yes, some of them are a bit ropey. Then again, Hardin himself used the odd example of parking meters in his original paper on the subject. When you say "just a negative externality", that's exactly what the TotC is all about. As Hardin himself has remarked, the word "externality" is a rather technical one that to some degree hides the somewhat unacceptable nature of what's going on. He suggested using the word "excretion" to more vividly illustrate the nature of "negative externalities".
- Regarding your example of urban sprawl, I think it could be classified as such. Your resource is "peace and tranquility" and it's eroded by people seeking the very thing. It's slightly different from the example of the pasture in that each concerned individual only makes a single decision (i.e. to move) rather than making a series of decisions (i.e. stock more this year?). Once you've moved there's nothing else you can do, it's up to other people to decide what happens next. Still, seems a reasonable example to me. Cheers, --Plumbago 08:17, 16 May 2006 (UTC)
- Yes, I agree that parable fits within the definition above and is not incorrect but I think using the term parable distracts. Because the subject is economics my vote goes to thought experiment or similar. Consider the parable of Schrödinger's cat. Also I do see that that dismissing an example as just a externality misses the point. However it is a poor example. A bar or fast food joint could also serve as examples, drunks, litter, but are not as clear as overfishing which overuses a resource directly to benfit unlike gambling. The sprawl is a better example from the point of veiw of a developer who buys farm and open land, subdivides then builds and sells lots. And...excretion is more vivid. Regards KAM 20:22, 16 May 2006 (UTC)
Pilgrims
According to whom were the Pilgrims an example of the Tragedy of the Commons? It's bad enough that we add one line examples without sources, but this is an essay. Unless we can find a source connecting the two, I think we should remove it. -Will Beback 20:40, 16 May 2006 (UTC)
- C. Fred Kleinknecht's letter [4] is not a reliable or noteworthy source, nor is this blog [5]. -Will Beback 22:39, 16 May 2006 (UTC)
- Fair enough. I was correcting an unsourced statement of the standard story, which I've certainly seen on quite a few occasions before. The blog cited gives a cite to a standard historical reference, so you might want to link that, but if you want to delete the whole thing, that's fine by me JQ 23:02, 16 May 2006 (UTC)
- That link would be useful in our article on the Pilgrims. But the extrapolation to this topic is more problematic. -Will Beback 23:15, 16 May 2006 (UTC)
- Fair enough. I was correcting an unsourced statement of the standard story, which I've certainly seen on quite a few occasions before. The blog cited gives a cite to a standard historical reference, so you might want to link that, but if you want to delete the whole thing, that's fine by me JQ 23:02, 16 May 2006 (UTC)
Game theory
The paragraph on the Prisoner's Dilemma reads like original research. First, a commons game is not a PD but a crowding game (an inverse Coordination game). Second, even if someone compared the TotC to a PD, it should be sourced, not stated like the editor made it up. ~ trialsanderrors 09:32, 23 June 2006 (UTC)
- In the tragedy of the commons, the optimal allocation of the scarce resource comes from all participants cooperating (limiting their use); the worst outcome occurs when everyone cheats. Each individual, however, does better in the short-run by cheating, so short-sighted or uncoordinated individual actors will cheat to the detriment of the group. This exactly describes the payoff matrix of a prisoner's dilemma:
Player 2 adopts strategy A Player 2 adopts strategy B Player 1 adopts strategy A 2,2 0,3 Player 1 adopts strategy B 3,0 1,1
Player 2 adopts strategy A Player 2 adopts strategy B Player 1 adopts strategy A 0,0 1,1 Player 1 adopts strategy B 1,1 0,0
- I also strongly disagree with your contention that this constitutes original research on a couple of grounds. First, the two concepts seem very closely related; I think that there is an obvious (no research required) connection to be made here, and that drawing attention to the prisoner's dilemma from this article provides usefull information for people interested in economic analysis of the tragedy of the commons. Second, a Google search for "prisoner's dilemma" "tragedy of the commons" turns up over 24,000 results! Those results include loads of articles both about prisoners dilemmas and about the tragedy of the commons.[6]
- I am removing the original research warning from this section (I think there have been far too many claims of original research in the discussion of this article), but I am happy to listen to arguments to the contrary.Btwied 18:43, 26 June 2006 (UTC)
- Actually, it reads a hell of a lot like original research to me, too - especially as the conclusion it reaches in re the interated prisoner's dilemma is pure and simple hogwash. If the defector were really punished in an interated game, there wouldn't be a tragedy of the commons. ElectricRay 23:58, 14 August 2006 (UTC)
Evolutionary psychology
The section on "evolutionary psychology" referred to this field as using the tragedy of the commons. While this is no doubt true, the author(s) of this text were referring to general evolutionary biology theory, not the more specific "evolutionary psychology". I have changed the title, and broadened this section to mention other areas of evolution where the tragedy of the commons is applied, as it is widely used in all aspects of evolution.
Definition
THE INTRODUCTORY PARAGRAPH DOES NOT DEFINE THE TERM! Sorry for caps locks, but that is quite an error.
- Fair point. Perhaps the "Introduction" section could furnish the relevant text. I'll see what I can do. Cheers, --Plumbago 14:51, 31 August 2006 (UTC)
From the one who wrote the above in caps: Here's a first sketch of a definition: The tragedy of the commons refers to phenomena in which individuals may, in the course of maximizing their own wealth (utility is a bit too opaque and esoteric, but I don't see much in the way of alternatives) overuse and thereby harm a common or public (perhaps one or the other will do) property, as in the case of over-grazing a public pasture. (This definition may be too specific, as it was written with a few examples in mind - I am not cognizant of all such tragedies of the commons). I've just realized, that a more popular usage of the term has been ignored entirely - tragedy of the commons often refers to how people mistreat public property simply because it's not theirs, eg, the graffiti in public bathrooms. Citations needed, I suppose.
Since the bathroom example doesn't really fit the definition, I'm going to remove it, unless anyone objects. Thehotelambush 20:20, 27 May 2007 (UTC)
Merge suggested: Tyranny of the Commons
Another article, Tyranny of the Commons, discusses exactly the same subject. It should be merged into this article. WVhybrid 03:23, 13 October 2006 (UTC)
- Possibly just redirect Tyranny here and add a short note about it into this article - it sounds pretty much the same as the Tragedy of the Commons. It does get into positive externalities (which doesn't sound like much of a "tyranny" to me), so I'm perhaps missing something important there. Cheers, --Plumbago 08:03, 13 October 2006 (UTC) (Counting as Merge --Bill Huston (talk) 00:40, 15 December 2006 (UTC))
- There Is a big difference between tragedy and tyrrany. Tragedy of the commons is something that law students worry about a lot in a philosophical way. When one talks about tyranny, it is with an economists eye. They should link each other, but they are different. --Evan nov 18 2006 (Counting as Keep --Bill Huston (talk) 00:40, 15 December 2006 (UTC))
- How are the above articles unique enough to be separated from Social trap? --DixiePixie 20:52, 20 November 2006 (UTC) (Counting as Merge BOTH into Social Trap --Bill Huston (talk) 00:43, 15 December 2006 (UTC))
- I'm for merging. I think the term is being widely applied, but that's because it's a very basic phenomenon, not because it's somehow different in economics/law/games theory/biology. The basics remain the same, so pointing to one centralized article that defines it and then describes the various applications is quite reasonable. suz 15:24, 6 December 2006 (UTC)
- Tragedy of the commons refers to the problem which is created when individuals using a resource do not themselves contribute to its maintainance. It is utility-maximization while at the same time ignoring Mill's utilitarian prerequisite that an action must be valued from the aggregate benefit it contributes to other actors. Tragedy of the commons is egoism. Tyranny of the commons is Rousseau's "volonté génerale", which implies that in a democracy the majority will always be the dictator of the minority. The two concepts are not philosophically related. The tyranny of the commons ought to be re-defined according to Rousseau's idea on the majority's right to ignore a minority in a democracy. As the article is now it is way off common knowledge in philosophy. Is this the Tragedy of Wikipedia, perhaps? Karl, Sweden —Preceding unsigned comment added by 85.226.219.41 (talk) 16:30, 14 December 2006 (Counting as Merge and redirect "Tyrrany of the Commons" to "Tyrrany of the Majority" --Bill Huston (talk) 00:43, 15 December 2006 (UTC))
- I'm for a merge and redirect "Tyranny of the Commons" to "Tyrrany of the Majority". Reasons:
- WVhybrid is correct. These two articles are talking about the same thing
- Notability: "tragedy of the commons" = 1,040,000 ghits, whereas "tyranny of the commons" = only 120 ghits (many are replications of the Wiki article)
- If you look at the ghits which are not the Wiki article, it appears that when people are talking about tyranny of the commons they are in fact refering to Tyranny of the majority. This is essentally what Karl,Sweden is saying also. -- Bill Huston (talk) 23:29, 14 December 2006 (UTC)
- Oppose merge of this article into Social trap. This is the more significant article, and is a well used phrase, per the google hit list above.WVhybrid 03:43, 15 December 2006 (UTC)
- Oppose (Would be for 'Merge and redirect "Tyranny of the Commons" to "Tyranny of the Majority"' per Karl's last comment.) Tyranny and Tragedy are entirely different things. jthillik 22:48, 17 December 2006 (UTC)
- Oppose all mergers herein discussed agree with Jfhillik. These are different things. Anlace 22:55, 16 January 2007 (UTC)
Common Property vs. Open Access (res nullius)
While there is a section in the article (Tragedy of the commons#Controversy) that deals with various concerns about Hardin's work, there is no real discussion (that I could find) regarding the problem that some scholars have pointed identified with Hardin (and his interpreters) notion of Common Property: Namely that what the tragedy is refereing not to common property (as the title unfortunately suggests), but rather to open access (no property rights defined). This is a critical mis-understanding because common property rights institutions may well be more efficient than private property institutions when transaction costs are sufficiently high (Where transaction costs are viewed as the cost of defining, monitoring, and enforcing property rights).
Should this just be added to the section on Contreversy or would it be best to place the discussion elsewhere on the article? Joel Kincaid 19:04, 28 January 2007 (UTC)
Changes
Some of the articles on list of modern commons seem to be repetitive, so I am going to remove them, and also organize the list into similar concepts (Earth-related, life-related, human-related).
I agree with the discussion above calling for the list to consist only of things that are notable (WP:N) and referenced (WP:NOR)—come on, graffiti is hardly a tragedy, and may even be considered high art. However, I will leave it on for now, so I don't anger those who find it tragic. − Twas Now ( talk • contribs • e-mail ) 02:01, 3 February 2007 (UTC)
Whither the parable
This article in the introductory sections talks about "the parable" without presenting it. If someone has a moment to lay it out it would likely make the article more understandable. -- cmhTC 02:00, 1 June 2007 (UTC)
- It's not a simple parable. It's currently covered in "Historical "commons"". The article sued to be shorter and it was nearer the beginning. Maybe we should simply move up that exception. ·:·Will Beback ·:· 03:54, 1 June 2007 (UTC)
Bees
Quote: "It is also widely used in studies of social insects, where scientists wish to understand why insect workers do not undermine the "common good" by laying eggs of their own and causing a breakdown of the society."
I think this example might be misleading because worker bees do undermine the "comman good" by laying eggs. However, those eggs are eaten by other worker bees who serve as a policing force to guard each other against cheating.
Conflict in the Bee Hive:Worker Reproduction and Worker Policing by Francis. L. W. Ratnieks http://www.lasi.group.shef.ac.uk/pdf/rbeekquart2002_conflictbeehive.pdf?id=23018400 - Ch qin 04:13, 16 June 2007 (UTC)
- Unless the author of the report uses the terms "commons" or "tragedy of the commns" I'm not sure we should add it here. There's a list of theim in the article, but I think they are based in the editor's opinions rather than upon those of scholars or other writers. ·:· Will Beback ·:· 08:56, 16 June 2007 (UTC)
- Oh, I am not suggesting that the above part be added to this article, I am merely questioning the accuracy of the quoted statement. The above quoted statement seems to imply that the scientists do not understand why "the tragedy of the commons" did not happen in insect societies. However, research had uncover the mechanics behind this and it does not contradict the "tragedy of the commons" at all. Perharps the quoted statement can be either removed or replaced with a more accurate description if the social insect example is somehow vital.
- Social insects seems to be unaffected by the "tragedy of the commons" as they are the model of altruistic behaviour, sacrificing their own reproductive potential for the common good. However, research had shown that honey bee workers act selfishly by laying their own eggs and are only keep in check by the worker bees policing each other. Similar mechanics might be behind other social insect societies as well. Ch qin 14:14, 16 June 2007 (UTC)
Modern solutions
I've made a few changes to the Modern solutions section. Essentially, I have expanded the paragraph that addresses the fact that governmental regulation is an important and common means of addressing the tragedy of the commons. Although privatization is one approach (after all, how can there be a tragedy if there are no commons?), many (most?) resources that fall into the category are commons specifically because they are difficult or impossible to privatize. Air, for instance. The atmosphere is a textbook example of the tragedy which noone could have any possible incentive for actually owning. Envirocorrector 15:33, 11 July 2007 (UTC)
Some Questions about the lead
There appear to be some inconsistencies in the lead. First, while the Grand Banks example seems reasonable, the Salmon example is misplaced -- this an example of using a resource (the river) either to generate biomass or energy -- this is not an example of a problem of the commons, but rather an example of competing uses of a resource (the dams might well serve the "common good" more effectively than the salmon. At best this is an infelicitous example.
Second, I'm not convinced that the Los Angeles example is a good choice either. While its been a long while since I've thought about water and property rights, I do believe that the law of ownership in the US is very different on the west and east coasts, with the western states having a long tradition of private ownership over water (makes sense -- water is much more scarce there, and the incentives that private ownership provide for conservation are thus more valuable in the west compared to the east).
Finally, could anyone offer an explanation of what is meant by "unrestricted demand". Lots of things it seems to me restrict demand...price, income, etc. To me this does not seem like a statement (unclear, unsourced) that should appear in the lead of an article as important as this. Corebreeches 18:32, 24 August 2007 (UTC)
Restructuring
I moved the examples from the intro into "modern commons." The order of some of the sub-headings is not logical (for instance, why doesn't 'controversy' come at the end?) and there is a lot of repetition. Also, the section on "modern commons" reads like a trivia section, so I'm restructuring into paragraph form. Many of the links (e.g. "life", "animals", "public housing") are too broad and, given the more specific examples which follow, unnecessary. - IstvanWolf 19:14, 25 September 2007 (UTC)
Comments
Perhaps the article should more rigidly segregate the classic "Tragedy of the Commons" and modern examples and, particularly, modern solutions. TOTC seems to me to be about the over-exploitation of a communal resource by a relatively small community.
As the manager of shared computer storage, I am living that nightmare! The resource is large, apparently infinite to each individual, but the system has crashed because, of a thousand users, a few individuals have managed to procure between a hundred and a thousand times their "share".
TOTC is a very seductive explanation of communal over-exploitation. It should be just that.
Then, we can discuss modern "examples". Global warming, overpopulation. Are these valid examples? I don't know. But, arguing about them has nothing to do with the historical thesis of TOTC. Kmeintjes 04:36, 5 November 2007 (UTC)
Descriptions of the Tragedy?
The tragedy is never actually described in this article. It talks as if the reader is already familiar with it and the actual tragedy can only be inferred from the discussion. The intro mentions that the name comes from a comparison with medieval villages, but does not describe the problem. The first section, "Meaning," immediately starts in with "The metaphor illustrates", but what is the metaphor? This has never been fully set out. From there is goes on with different people's comments, but still never gives a complete description. It would really be beneficial to those mostly or entirely unfamiliar with the tragedy to have the first section give a detailed description of the metaphor and the problem.24.167.151.237 (talk) 01:33, 6 December 2007 (UTC)
- Maybe there've been one too many restructurings. But under "Meaning" is a fair, if somewhat lengthy description, nd if you follow thyough with it you'll get a good description:
- The metaphor illustrates how free access and unrestricted demand for a finite resource ultimately structurally dooms the resource through over-exploitation. This occurs because the benefits of exploitation accrue to individuals or groups, each of whom is motivated to maximize use of the resource to the point in which they become reliant on it, while the costs of the exploitation are distributed among all those to whom the resource is available (which may be a wider class of individuals than that which is exploiting it). This, in turn, causes demand for the resource to increase, which causes the problem to snowball to the point in which the resource is exhausted.
- In other words, if something is available for free, it will be overexploited and then it'll be gone. The problem with the metaphor is that it's based on a historical form of land-ownership which worked well, so there was no tragedy in the real "commons". ·:· Will Beback ·:· 04:20, 6 December 2007 (UTC)
- I've tried to straighten things out by restructuring. I've also moved the rather wordy and obfuscating quotations by the great philosophers to the reflist. The section describing Hardin's essay should cover the tragedy pretty well, and the "Meaning" section following it does somewhat focus on its central points. Still, I'm probably not the best judge having been familiar with the essay since a undergrad - I probably can't see the wood for the trees! Cheers, --Plumbago (talk) 13:04, 6 December 2007 (UTC)
Another modern commons example
Have you observed as I often do that crowd behaviour at busy airport baggage reclaims is collectively inefficient when a few individuals eager to catch sight of their luggage press close to the conveyer and block the view and access of others? Do you agree that this serves as a modern example of "tragic" (i.e. unfortunate) exercise of freedoms to use a commons (i.e. shared space)? How do you feel about my restoring the following example to the article? Crowd behaviour at airport baggage reclaim. More people would see and reach their luggage quickly if everyone waiting stood back from the conveyer. Cuddlyable3 (talk) 16:53, 6 December 2007 (UTC)
- A) Yes, that's a form of it.
- B) It's so trivial that the "tragic" element is missing.
- C) It's original research. If a noteworthy person writes an article applying the TOTC to baggage claim then we might include it. But we shouldn't sit around thinking up examples on our own. ·:· Will Beback ·:· 19:09, 6 December 2007 (UTC)
- No, cant add that because its original research. Brusegadi (talk) 22:30, 6 December 2007 (UTC)
- Brusegadi I believe it is incorrect to label as "original research" something that is apparent every day to anyone who cares to look in a busy airport, is reflected in the layout of baggage reclaim halls all over the world and I expect can be verified in the literature that baggage conveyer makers produce and airport architects use. Will Beback, it is a little hard to know your argument when you make 3 statements where your A) is straightforward, B) seems not to digest the notion of "tragic" here being a metaphor for a suboptimal consequence, and in C) you seem to reserve a hidden standard about who is "noteworthy" enough to write anything about TOTC (actually Modern Commons here) after Hardin.Cuddlyable3 (talk) 17:11, 7 December 2007 (UTC)
- I feel that you are taking this personal. Dont. Adding that would be OR. If you want you can file a request for comment. Without mention in the literature, you simply should not add it. Its not an 'obvious truth' and, if we started adding anything that fits the defenition, we would have a very long list and the article is not a list. Brusegadi (talk) 22:30, 7 December 2007 (UTC)
- Brusegadi and Will Beback are correct here. No matter how correct a particular statement might be, if it is unverifiable through reliable sources it has no place here. Encyclopedias document existing knowledge, they are not supposed to be a source of new knowledge. As an aside, there are a couple of examples in the article at present that are unsourced, and they should really be dealt with too (if a source cannot be found, they should be deleted). Cheers, --Plumbago (talk) 07:59, 8 December 2007 (UTC)
- It seems a shame that Hardin is now gone and verification of this will be difficult or not considered from a reliable source by your criteria. I suppose if someone set up an astroturf institute someplace it might become credible, reliable and verifiable. I think Dan Sullivan is still alive, and this link is in other wiki articles related to geolibertarianism. It may even be in Libertarian Party at Sea on Land, by Harold Kyriazi, but I haven't gotten around to reading that yet.
- The tragedy of the common misunderstanding
- "In their search for excuses to deny any common right to land, royal libertarians are fond of citing Garrett Hardin's work, "Tragedy of the Commons." Or at least they cite the title, which is all most royal libertarians are familiar with. Hardin is himself an advocate of land value taxation, and has criticized misinterpretations of his work with the lament that "The title of my 1968 paper should have been `The Tragedy of the Unmanaged Commons.'" [Emphasis Hardin's]--76.103.124.111 (talk) 17:52, 11 December 2007 (UTC)
- Hardin did not find air travel situations too trivial to mention:
Our government has paid out billions of dollars to create a supersonic transport which would disturb 50,000 people for every one person whisked from coast to coast 3 hours faster. Advertisers muddy the airwaves of radio and television and pollute the view of travelers.--"Tragedy of the Commons" by Garrett Hardin.Cuddlyable3 (talk) 22:10, 22 December 2007 (UTC)
Article for Deletion
William Forster Lloyd introduced a parable (?) TTOTC about pastureland. Then Garrett Hardin looked for comparable examples in [7], which are not hard to identify anywhere short-term interests dominate, and which is OR by GH. GH wrote some interesting things but I don't see that GH ever elevated TTOTC to a popular metaphor. Can anyone give better attention to WP:RS and WP:V to save TTOTC from becoming a WP:AFD? - in other words WP:PROVEIT ! Cuddlyable3 (talk) 14:38, 13 December 2007 (UTC)
- Hi Cuddlyable3. I think that AFDing is perhaps somewhat over the top. A quick check with Web of Knowledge reveals that Hardin's original paper (in a reliable source) has been cited by more than 3000 other scientific papers, so you could try trawling the scientific literature for evidence of the notability of Hardin's work (it's readily verifiable, but I'm probably missing the point of your objection on this point). It's certainly true that the TOTC is not a metaphor commonly used in everyday discourse, but it is routinely used in scientific discourse. Anyway, it may be the case that its notability is not adequately demonstrated in the main text. Do you have any suggestions for the kind of supporting evidence that you'd like to see for this? Cheers, --Plumbago (talk) 15:27, 13 December 2007 (UTC)
- AFDing exposes the question of whether we want Wikipedia filled with commentary articles such as the present TTOTC. Search engine hit counting alone is not the criterion for WP:V, not least because it is blind to the reasons for citings and to citings back, directly or indirectly, to Wikipedia itself. Plumbago you mention a count of citings of Garrett Hardin's paper but TTOTC itself is only a passing mention found within that paper of a melodramatic lament over an arcadian [[8]] pastoral might-have-been.
If it is numbers you want then a count of editors who have made contributions (that are still there) to TTOTC gives a guide to how many can be said to have a vested interest in keeping the article, but that is only an indication relative to other articles. At this point I take issue with Plumbago's assertion that TTOTC is routinely used in scientific discourse. Scientists may talk about anything they like but scientific method deals with hypotheses that have demonstrable predictions, and do not confuse mere labelling with actual discovery. Does the metaphor TTOTC predict anything in quantifiable terms? Does it clarify or obfuscate when it apparently needs more effort to explain than it explains? Finally, a question that may worry me more than it worries you: does membership in a herd who vote that TTOTC is noteworthy constitute vain elitism? Cuddlyable3 (talk) 14:36, 15 December 2007 (UTC)
- Cuddlyable3, you seem to be confusing Web of Knowledge with an internet search engine. The 3000 number I mentioned above is the number of times this one paper has been cited by other papers in the scientific literature. Most scientific papers are lucky if they are cited more than a handful of times. A well-respected and influential paper may be cited several hundred times. To be cited several thousand times is more notable. It may well be that many of the citations are negative, it's unlikely that the majority are - poorly-received papers quietly disappear from the scientific literature, they are not repeatedly cited over a ~40 year period.
- Regarding whether TOTC makes quantifiable predictions, that's simply not pertinent to this discussion. You're suggesting that a notable, verifiable subject that was originally published in a reliable source (and subsequently cited many times in other reliable sources) should be subjected to an AFD. It may well be that the article could do with a section on the rigor of the TOTC, but that's not what's being proposed here - although it's the sort of thing that should be proposed, at least as a stalking horse, before an AFD.
- Finally, I'm not quite sure what to make of "does membership in a herd who vote that TTOTC is noteworthy constitute vain elitism?". Are you trying to be rude? Anyway, it doesn't matter either way. By all means nominate this article for deletion, but I'd advise that it's unlikely to succeed because TOTC is, like it or not, a notable subject. --Plumbago (talk) 10:00, 17 December 2007 (UTC)
- All the editors who have worked industriously on this article merit respect and any rudeness seen on my part would be both unwarranted and counterproductive to points I am making. I hope my apology reassures Plumbago whom I recognise as one of those editors with a natural and legitimate vested interest in the article.
- My point about the citations is that they are of Hardin's PAPER which I agree contains notable analysis coupled with many examples, but of these perhaps the most whimsical and furthest from hard science is TTOTC, also used as the title for its dramatic appeal. Thus it is more like packaging than content, and Hardin himself is tentative about promoting it as a binding principle.
- My question "Does the metaphor TTOTC predict anything in quantifiable terms?" is relevant to a claim that TTOTC belongs in scientific discourse. I am also interested to hear what Plumbago thinks might be added to the article in a section on the rigor of the TOTC that does not conflict with WP:NOR. Cuddlyable3 (talk) 13:49, 17 December 2007 (UTC)
- Cuddly, I think that you misapprehend the application of non scientific method approaches to science as she is actually practiced. Consider that, if Lysenkoism had (without itself being quantifiable without fraud) actually generated several testable theories about genetics (or for that matter astrophysics) it would have been useful to science. It didn't, but that doesn't really affect my argument.
- The Popperian structure of science covers only the philosophically accessible bits. What it wzs in the omnibus that day that caused Kekule to think of a ring structure is not very accessible to those who look at the functioning of science and scientists. Nor what it was about his sea voyage that led Chandrasakar to ponder the upper mass bound a star could retain throughout its life and death. Nor what made Galileo so productive, and yet let him make badly wrong estimates of structural loadings. Or Archimedes to be receptive to his realization of density measurement. Eureka!
- Neither Popper, nor any other modern, has made much headway into the creative aspects of science. Any science. Thus your objection to the TOTC as a no-quantifiable theory is misplaced. It is useful in analyzing situations, and that sufficies, for those analyses easily include quantifiable theories. In any case, you have nglected the evident fact that economics, as it has been practiced by Smith, Bentham, Keynes, Friedman, Arrow, Black/Scholes, etc etc is not a science. Perhaps Khaneman and Tversky are scientific in their approach, but it is really a branch of experimental psychology and hasn't yet been extended really well to large economic questions. So, TOTC is really a political issue, or a traditional economic issued (based as it is on the mythical homo economicus), not science at all. Unless you count the inspriation it has provided to investigate scientific questions.
- Not an article for any sort of deletion list. ww (talk) 19:52, 18 December 2007 (UTC)
Ww, here is what I understand from your post regarding AfD:
- you don't want the present article TOTC deleted
- TOTC is, you say, not science at all.
The latter point, and your implied answer NO to my question "Does the metaphor predict anything in quantifiable terms?" seem quite consistent. You say:
- "It is useful in analyzing situations." Does that analysis consist of anything more than claiming "Ahah! I recognize this situation as yet another example of TOTC!", in other words more labelling than analysis? Recent editing has removed rather than encouraged post-Hardin observations of TOTC from the article. Cuddlyable3 (talk) 22:12, 20 December 2007 (UTC)
- Any analytic tool which leads one to think in new directions can be useful. ToTC has done so in many cases, hence I think, its continued vitality in so many intellectual disciplines. Again, as I suggested, none of this has anything to do with deleting the article. It should stay because of its long term and continuing interest to many. It qualifies on that ground alone. WP is not in the business of tidying up the odd interests of humanity by including or excluding particular topics which seem untidy or insufficiently scientific <or whatever> to some, but in recording them for future reference. ww (talk) 22:20, 24 December 2007 (UTC)
Basis in evolutionary theory?
The article states that "The idea comes from the theory that individuals will always behave selfishly in order to maximise their fitness."
I think this is a mis-statement. Individuals don't try to maximize their fitness - they try to survive and reproduce. In doing so, they compete for resources, and those better-adapted to compete are those who happen to be "more fit" for the current competition. The statement perhaps confuses an individual's physical fitness (I want to be well-fed and healthy in order to better compete) with his or her genetic fitness (I have genes that make me stronger/faster/more efficient).
I suggest "... individuals will usually behave selfishly in a competition for survival" as the more accurate statement. ("Usually," in view of recent evidence for a genetic basis for altruism.) You can make it a "Darwinian competition" if you want to risk inciting more debate.
Not adept at editing WP (it used to be simpler, back in the day...) so I'll leave it to one of the regulars to consider this.
66.108.184.224 (talk) 01:20, 7 March 2008 (UTC)James Demers
- I am not sure, I recall a definition of fitness that involved reproductive success. Yet, I am not sure, I will read the article carefully... Brusegadi (talk) —Preceding comment was added at 06:43, 7 March 2008 (UTC)
It's the "in order to" phrase that I object to. It implies an intent to become more fit, when in fact one has no control over one's fitness (in the Darwinian sense) -- it's dictated by one's genes. —Preceding unsigned comment added by 66.108.184.224 (talk) 23:26, 8 March 2008 (UTC)
- I agree and have removed the "in order to" phrase. I also toned down the claim that TOTC "features highly in the field of evolutionary biology" which is purported by reference to Dionisio & Gordo who write as recently as 2006 "To our knowledge, this is the first time that rivalry and excludability of goods have been discussed in the context of evolutionary problems." I introduced separate headings for applications to evolutionary biology and social evolution, plus some tidying.Cuddlyable3 (talk) 10:04, 21 April 2008 (UTC)
Introduction Paragraph
I don't like the introduction paragraph for this article, its a bit long and the last 2 or 3 paragraphs, the ones discussing a debate about sustainability, should really be put somewhere in the body of the article. 123.243.215.92 (talk) 09:54, 20 October 2011 (UTC)
- The difficulty with the introductory paragraph is that it does more than mention Hardin's paper (the details of which deserve separate treatment) without including as it should, the present-day expression of this tragedy namely the loss of fishing opportunities world-wide, due to over-fishing (and for that matter whale over-killing too). Macrocompassion (talk) 11:24, 24 October 2011 (UTC)
- Furthermore, it's not certain that the dilemma of the commons was first discussed by Hardin in 1968; rather, Harold Demsetz had a 1967 article, Toward a Theory of Property Rights, 57 The American Economic Review 347 (May, 1967). Although Hardin's article may be more widely cited, it appears that Demsetz' was first. — Preceding unsigned comment added by 63.229.198.12 (talk) 23:48, 14 December 2011 (UTC)
- The Malthusian Theory about over-consumption compared to population growth could usefully be included here too, since it was how people looked at this problem in the early days. — Preceding unsigned comment added by Macrocompassion (talk • contribs) 11:34, 24 October 2011 (UTC)
The concept is now widely understood without any reference to Hardin at all. And the article makes clear with historical examples that the general problem was understood 2400 years ago. Hardin can be removed from the opening paragraph, and "Theories and examples" reworked. This isn't an article about Hardin's academic influence.
The Tragedy is not necessarily with any individual, but with people's lack of understanding of the larger social consequences of their action? Not sure about that. 76.102.1.193 (talk) 07:01, 15 June 2012 (UTC)
- Hardin should stay in the lede (opening paragraph(s)) as he is widely associated with this idea. Note the reasons & possible language suggested below in Talk:Tragedy_of_the_commons#Lede_a_little_too_strong_on_Hardin.3F. Lentower (talk) 11:16, 15 June 2012 (UTC)
Real, existing commons
Do you think there should be some mention of the fact that there had been commons in england for the best part of a thousand years, without any of Hardin's predictions occurring? I think it'd put the article in perspective to note that the theory is proving an outcome sharply in contrast to the last thousand years of real-life evidence. —Preceding unsigned comment added by 82.118.113.164 (talk) 14:12, 12 August 2009 (UTC)
Another possible example is flat-rate Internet, which encourages over-consumption and capping of bandwidth. With pricing based on used bandwidth, ISPs would instead have an incentive to increase capacity and encourage more use. -- SpareSimian (talk) 05:50, 15 November 2009 (UTC)
- nope, your abundantly wrong. Also, not a common at all: they sold it to you. Go somewhere else.Scientus (talk) 08:59, 19 November 2009 (UTC)
No Social Science Research Section
A social psychologist (or grad students thereof) really should spend some time putting in a decent summary of the literature and findings. In particular, the various methods and outcomes are critical for understanding the impact of Tragedy of Commons for policy-makers. Experiments varying replenishment rates, reinforcement rates, and consequences have led to the same exhaustion outcome, at a faster or slower rate. Don't have time to get to this today, myself, but it is critical for this article! JasonRin (talk) 17:43, 15 May 2012 (UTC)
Merge from Commons dilemma
- The following discussion is closed. Please do not modify it. Subsequent comments should be made in a new section. A summary of the conclusions reached follows.
- The result was merge Commons dilemma into Tragedy of the commons. -- Debate 木 23:23, 25 August 2008 (UTC)
These two articles are on the same topic, and both have detail the other lack. Cheers. --AtD (talk) 11:55, 25 March 2008 (UTC)
- Agree: I think the main article should be titled "Tragedy of the Commons" and not "Commons Dilemma". ElectricRay (talk) 17:26, 20 April 2008 (UTC)
- Contingent agree. Electric is correct that the title of a merged article should be TOTC. But the Commons Dilemma article is very much in the way of describing an academic field, not a general account of the topic. So, if it's added, I think it should be in a shortish section more or less titled academic study. Lots of references, maybe. Otherwise, I'm opposed. ww (talk) 02:48, 10 May 2008 (UTC)
- Contingent agree. The Commons dilemma article has some glaring problems:
- The introduction is a tad too short, leaving out the part that explains why herders feel that they can put more cows on land that is already borderline or worse.
- In the third paragraph on motivational factors, it concludes "The most likely explanation is that people have an optimistic bias". Need a source for this. I could just as easily conclude a pessimistic bias: "Well, I don't know how much is left, so maybe I should get as much as I can".
- In the Strategic Factors paragraph, it says "The interpretation of this effect is that the first players feel entitled to take more.". Again, I'd like to see a reference for this; they could just as easily be thinking "wow, there's plenty for everyone, so I can take lots!", while the latecmers see how fast the supply is dwindling, and therefore take less.
- In the Structural Factors paragraph, it says "Another structural solution is the privatization of the commons and this has been very effective in experimental and field research", which seems to contradict what the TOTC article says, that it leads to anti-tragedy.
- ww says: "Add a shortish section". That article is already rather short. I'd say just swallow the whole thing.
- There are plenty of references in that article, none online, which makes it hard for non-specialists to verify.
- --Scott McNay (talk)
- Agree Looks like there is consensus to merge. I'll do the merge and clean up over the next week or two. Both articles have some glaring problems that I'll have a go at correcting at the same time. Debate 木 23:19, 25 August 2008 (UTC)
Paradoxically?
"Paradoxically, Hardin's article has been interpreted as an argument both for the privatization of community assets and for increased government regulation."
Paradoxically? Really? "Interestingly," perhaps--but I don't think it's paradoxical.
Anyone else have any thoughts on this?
philiptdotcom (talk) 02:23, 3 October 2008 (UTC)
P.S. - It's not paradoxical, because both the solutions mentioned [potentially] solve the "commons dilemma" [at least to some extent]; however, the BENEFICIARIES of the reduced impacts may be significantly different. philiptdotcom (talk) 02:27, 3 October 2008 (UTC)
- I'm happy with rewording the sentence, either with the word 'interestingly' or through some other reconstruction. The use of paradoxically in this context was a poor choice of words on my part. Debate 木 08:47, 3 October 2008 (UTC)
- I have been bold and replaced the word with 'controversially'. I am still happy for others to have a crack if that change is itself controversial. Debate 木 08:52, 3 October 2008 (UTC)
- Hi there Debate. I've removed "controversially" since it's not controversial that Hardin's idea has been used in this way (certainly not to Hardin, who would probably have taken the view that no one solution fits all commons problems). "Interestingly" would have been better, but it still implies a judgement on the part of WP editors rather than something source-able. The sentence makes sense without any leading word, so I've removed any for now. I hope that's OK. Cheers, --PLUMBAGO 08:58, 3 October 2008 (UTC)
- That's fine with me. Debate 木 08:59, 3 October 2008 (UTC)
- I rewrote it as: Hardin's article has been variously interpreted either as an argument for the privatization of community assets or for increased government regulation. Cuddlyable3 (talk) 17:31, 3 October 2008 (UTC)
- Can we get sources for these interpretations? ·:· Will Beback ·:· 17:51, 3 October 2008 (UTC)
- Go for it. Debate 木 00:41, 4 October 2008 (UTC)
- I interpret that as "boldly delete the unsourced material". ·:· Will Beback ·:· 00:42, 4 October 2008 (UTC)
- How about boldy contribute some sources rather than simply hitting the delete key to every unsourced statement, of which there are still too many in this article, simply to make a point. References aren't that hard to find and several editors above don't appear to find the overall sentence objectionable. To save you some time, try clicking on the article above under "This page has been cited as a source by a media organization". Regardless, the article touches on the topic in several places and as the into is essentially a summary sourcing is only necessary if you think it is.Debate 木 00:55, 4 October 2008 (UTC)
- I interpret that as "boldly delete the unsourced material". ·:· Will Beback ·:· 00:42, 4 October 2008 (UTC)
- The burden is on those who add material. But really I was just asking, on this talk page, which sources we're summarizing by drawing attention to this "paradox". Who are the people who make these contradictory assertions? ·:· Will Beback ·:· 00:57, 4 October 2008 (UTC)
- This is beginning to turn into a discussion on sourcing, and probably needs it's own section. Regardless, there remains a fair amount of cleanup to do following a merge. The sources for The Commons Dilemma section are at the bottom of the page, separate from the reflist, and need to be integrated into the text and reflist (unfortunately they were never in-line citations). Due to a crazy life at the moment I haven't had the opportunity, but the work is waiting to be done if someone wants to jump in and do it. Debate 木 01:02, 4 October 2008 (UTC)
- BTW, seriously, the link I point out above gives you a start in answering your last question.Debate 木 01:04, 4 October 2008 (UTC)
- Which link? ·:· Will Beback ·:· 01:37, 4 October 2008 (UTC)
- Quote: "This page has been cited as a source by a media organization. The citation is in: Steigerwald, Bill (April 17, 2005). "Four economic precepts for everyday life", Pittsburgh Tribune-Review. (details)" Debate 木 09:22, 4 October 2008 (UTC)
- Thanks, that wasn't clear. But I hope we're not summarizing 13-year-old Tobin's views on this. "According to one newspaper columnist's 13-year old nephew, the 'Tragedy of the Commons' is a call for privatization...." Presumably, sentences like the one we're discussing here concern significant viewpoints that appear in reliable sources. Since we're arguing over how to summarize their views, I'm just asking who "they" are: these people whose views we're describing. If we're not sure whose ideas we're summarizing then maybe that would be the best place to start. ·:· Will Beback ·:· 10:43, 4 October 2008 (UTC)
- Quote: "This page has been cited as a source by a media organization. The citation is in: Steigerwald, Bill (April 17, 2005). "Four economic precepts for everyday life", Pittsburgh Tribune-Review. (details)" Debate 木 09:22, 4 October 2008 (UTC)
- Which link? ·:· Will Beback ·:· 01:37, 4 October 2008 (UTC)
<outdent> As I said, it's a start. Regardless, the term "they" is rightly not used in the sentence as it simply summaries two general schools of thought taken by a wide variety of commentators, as well as an implicit tension within Hardin's article itself, and is already extensively covered in the body of the text. The {{who}} tag, which appears to me to better characterize your concerns rather than {{fact}}, is therefore in my view unnecessarily pedantic. Nonetheless, if you wished to do some digging I am confident that you would find numerous sources that would resolve your concerns, including from within the extensive existing reference list. Unfortunately, as I don't have the time at the moment to follow that up for you please be bold and either do a little research yourself and contribute to improving the article or delete whatever chunks you see fit. Debate 木 12:04, 4 October 2008 (UTC)
- Late to this party but I had come across this before and posted it on some discussion thread related to Hardin but here it is. Hardin is alleged to have "lamented":
- "The title of my 1968 paper should have been `The Tragedy of the Unmanaged Commons.'" [Emphasis Hardin's]
- http://geolib.com/essays/sullivan.dan/royallib.html
- If accurate, it suggests some displeasure with misinterpretation of his original essay.24.5.167.23 (talk) 17:16, 25 May 2009 (UTC)
Mentioned commons dilema in intro
- I added info about the commons dilemma to the introduction. This is necessary because the dilemma is central to Hardin's article, and the article is not the first or last study of the essence of the dilemma. I believe many people are familiar with the phrase "tragedy of the commons" as representing the dilemma of the commons itself, rather than the article. -Pgan002 (talk) 02:43, 16 October 2008 (UTC)
- The essence of the commons dilemma has been discussed by theorists since ancient history, but not under that name.
- What is our source for that sentence? ·:· Will Beback ·:· 03:29, 16 October 2008 (UTC)
- References 6, 7, 8 and 9. -Pgan002 (talk) 18:34, 16 October 2008 (UTC)
- Thanks. The assertion that Thucydides and Aristotle were talking about the same concept is close to original research, but it's probably OK. ·:· Will Beback ·:· 18:39, 16 October 2008 (UTC)
- References 6, 7, 8 and 9. -Pgan002 (talk) 18:34, 16 October 2008 (UTC)
Several Dead white males were used in the 18 and 19 to motivate to get rid of the commons,there is no continuity of the discussion since the attic Polis. Radkau is very clear abut that point. --Polentario (talk) 14:34, 16 January 2009 (UTC)
- Radkau is cited in the intro, with no explanation of whom he is. —Preceding unsigned comment added by 24.215.171.4 (talk) 02:35, 15 November 2009 (UTC)
Oak tree
its rather typical for a former commons used by pigs to be fed with oaks. --Polentario (talk) 01:23, 20 January 2009 (UTC)
Third Opininion concerning Wikimedia Commons and Allmende
(Copy from wiki portal) Is there any sourced etymology about Wikimedia 'Commons', e.g. in relation with the historical Common land and Tragedy of the Commons or Tragedy of the anticommons ? The direct German Translation of commons is be 'Allmende'. Both have been used in GB and germany (according reliable sources e.g. Joachim Radkau) since the 18th in an metaphorical way for the challenges of Common good (economics)s respectively de:Gemeingut. Thanks for any advice. --Polentario (talk) 19:55, 21 January 2009 (UTC)
Costa Rica is the first country to avoid the tragedy of the commons, by pricing for environmental business services to preserve eco-tourism
The country of Costa Rica has successfully advanced the growth of its eco-tourism business by taking account of, and pricing for, the environmental business services consumed by pollution.[1]
- ^ THOMAS L. FRIEDMAN (No) Drill, Baby, Drill New York Times Op-Ed Column Published: April 11, 2009 http://www.nytimes.com/2009/04/12/opinion/12friedman.html?em
Missing the Point
Critics of Harden’s paper “The Tragedy of the Commons” continue to miss his point. In seeking to criticise some of the examples he used, or seeking to demonstrate that his examples were inaccurate, those critics have deflected their attention completely from the central thesis in Harden’s paper. That thesis is that the Earth is a finite resource, and, a finite resource can only support a finite objective – in this case, population. Ergo, if we don’t control the world’s population we are all doomed to suffer. What Harden did not state was the time period before this would occur. The paper was written in 1968. A little over forty years later (2009), with increased numbers enduring poverty, global warming, and other associated social ills, it would seem that we (with one exception) are ignoring Harden’s timely warning at our peril. That one exception is China which moved to impose their one child policy on its population a number of years ago. 203.129.48.106 (talk) 04:06, 14 November 2009 (UTC)
Criticisms, NPOV, More Citations Needed
The current citation in the controversy section (which I have more appropriately labeled "Criticism" in keeping with other articles) is insufficient. Specifically, the article references a public policy expert in a journal article.
This is not a historian commenting on historical fact. The issue here is whether or not land enclosures were managed to prevent overgrazing. The article claimed that "Historical Studies have proven" and then cited a journal article specifically attacking Hardin, not a journal article about common land. Dahlman, who was cited in the article, is a public policy expert, not a historian, and it is not sufficient to cite his work when challenging an idea accepted by consensus within the historical community.
This is a historical claim: It requires historical sources. A journal of 18th century british history for example.
Please see Wikipedia for more information. Specifically: "claims that are contradicted by the prevailing view within the relevant community."
I have edited the article slightly to fix the immediate problem ("Historical studies have proven") but the whole section needs significant cleanup. For example, I left the rather POV statement about there being errors within the article. I don't know which errors he's talking about, however. It would be good to have that sources perspective, though, as he is an economic expert.
That's one of the problems with The Tragedy of the Commons. The work bridges Biology, Economics, History and Political and Moral Philosophy. Regarding criticisms, we need appropriate sources from appropriate arenas.--Ollie Garkey (talk) 20:26, 23 November 2009 (UTC)
Add The Age of Stupid?
Add The Age of Stupid? 99.155.159.95 (talk) 08:03, 22 April 2010 (UTC)
Dennis Fox quote
The whole paragraph regarding the Dennis Fox comments (added 05:06, 31 May 2007) is broken and is pretty weak anyway.
First, it is one large quote with a cursory introduction.
Second, much of the quote is actually a quote of a quote with Fox quoting Edney. And, the referencing of Edney is totally useless because it is simply a copy-paste of the references in Fox that are now incomplete.
Third, the quote-within-a-quote is incorrectly formatted and un-terminated making it unclear what is quoted text. Everything after "he stated" to the end of the paragraph is quoted from Fox.
Fourth, the online version of the Fox paper referenced contains a warning that it "does not exactly match the published version." If we want to quote this paper someone should dig out a reference for the American Psychologist version of the paper and check the quoted text.
Fifth, the quote-within-a-quote (of Edney by Fox) has now grown a "[sic]" after the "well-functioning commons" which is not present in the online version of Fox's paper. I don't see what requires the use of the heavy-handed 'sic' notation here; perhaps the singular 'commons' is causing confusion?
The idea presented by Fox in this paragraph is intriguing. Perhaps someone can summarize Fox and Edney. Or summarize Fox and quote Edney directly. Or summarize Fox and quote the "Dunbar's number" page.
Non-illustrative picture
The picture (http://en.wiki.x.io/wiki/File:Lacanja_burn.JPG) in this article is an example of [deforestation]; it is not an example of "Tragedy of the Commons". Thus, it should not appear as a leading graphic in the summary of the article.
There is no objection to the picture appearing somewhere else in the article, perhaps as an illustration of one of the concepts associated with the dilemma. —Preceding unsigned comment added by MechHead (talk • contribs) 16:37, 4 August 2010 (UTC)
- The picture of the cows in field that is currently there is more appropriate. Although, hmm, it may be a little obscure to modern readers. Interpretation 1) One animal eats the grass, the others can't ... that's somewhat intuitive. Interpretation 2) Cows and other animals can overgraze land, leading to soil damage. Ok, true, but not in the experience of most readers. Interpretation 3) Communal lands, historically, were sometimes carefully regulated, so that no one person obliviously took what someone else also needed. Very obscure, for historians only.
- However, all those interpretations are a little tangential. The problem was stated to us by our Systems Analysis professor perhaps in a way that is more readily grasped: There is a worn track in the lawn, outside the classroom. People walk on grass all the time. It recovers. The problem is that when more than a particular number of people walk over a spot of grass, it dies. The tragedy is that no one is really trying to kill the grass. And no one knows whether their feet will make no difference, or will be the last straw that kills the grass. Up until that point -- there's no problem. The first person past that point has done something, unintentionally, that has a serious consequence. 24.130.145.204 (talk) 03:36, 19 August 2010 (UTC)
Identity politics?
Is there any reason why this article is in Category:Identity politics? I've read a bit about both but can't immediately see a connection. —Tom Morris (talk) 17:05, 14 December 2010 (UTC)
- Hmm. Looks like a tenuous connection to me. I'll remove it (feel free to revert, anyone, if you know better :-) bobrayner (talk) 19:02, 14 December 2010 (UTC)
Spam is not an example of the commons dillema
I would argue this is not an appropriate example. First of all, spam is sustainable. It is not and has never been expected that spam will entirely kill email. Secondly the normal use case is that of users using a common good in the same way but collectively overusing it for maximizing their own profit. This does not apply to spam. Spammers are a minority and their practice is a nuisance to other users, but does not threaten their own practice, nor is it confined to the short term... —Preceding unsigned comment added by 178.117.48.185 (talk) 22:56, 9 May 2011 (UTC)
commons vs. public good
These edits added Wikimedia commons and Creative Commons, which should be sensible, given their names, but they don't fit with the notion of commons as in the tragedy of the commons. A commons is generally considered a non-excludable, rival good, whereas things like Wikimedia aren't really rival, excluding slight bandwidth use issues. They really fit more into the notion of public goods. CRETOG8(t/c) 03:23, 13 May 2011 (UTC)
Orwell's Writings on Commons
George Orwell had a thing or two to say about enclosure. In "As I Please," Tribune, 18 August, 1944 http://wintermute10.tripod.com/AIP-35.htm he writes
Apropos of my remarks on the railings round London squares, a correspondent writes: ‘Are the squares to which you refer public or private properties? If private, I suggest that your comments in plain language advocate nothing less than theft, and should be classed as such.’
If giving the land of England back to the people of England is theft, I am quite happy to call it theft. In his zeal to defend private property, my correspondent does not stop to consider how the so-called owners of the land got hold of it. They simply seized it by force, afterwards hiring lawyers to provide them with title-deeds. In the case of the enclosure of the common lands, which was going on from about 1600 to 1850, the landgrabbers did not even have the excuse of being foreign conquerors; they were quite frankly taking the heritage of their own countrymen, upon no sort of pretext except that they had the power to do so.
Except for the few surviving commons, the high roads, the lands of the National Trust, a certain number of parks, and the sea shore below high-tide mark, every square inch of England is ‘owned’ by a few thousand families. These people are just about as useful as so many tapeworms. It is desirable that people should own their own dwelling houses, and it is probably desirable that a farmer should own as much land as he can actually farm. But the ground-landlord in a town area has no function and no excuse for existence. He is merely a person who has found out a way of milking the public while giving nothing in return. He causes rents to be higher, he makes town planning more difficult, and he excludes children from green spaces: that is literally all that he does, except to draw his income. The removal of the railings in the squares was a first step against him. It was a very small step, and yet an appreciable one, as the present move to restore the railings shows. For three years or so the squares lay open, and their sacred turf was trodden by the feet of working-class children, a sight to make dividend-drawers gnash their false teeth. It that is theft, all I can say is, so much the better for theft.
For that matter, Enclosure might make a good addition to the article. Thoughts?
Staysharp (talk) 21:11, 30 August 2011 (UTC)
- Orwell's diatribe is aimed at class enemies that he demonises as false-toothed tapeworms who give nothing in return. However Orwell's moral outrage offers no better compensation than Captain Pouch's pouch (see article) for his simplistic equating of functioning capitalism with theft. The treading of common green spaces by "feet of working-class children" that he envisions hardly sets the scene for a Tragedy of overgrazing of the Commons. Orwell's text could only be related to Hardin's essay if the latter debated for or against Marxist revolution, but Hardin does neither. Cuddlyable3 (talk) 16:47, 31 August 2011 (UTC)
Lede a little too strong on Hardin?
Not an expert on this subject, but just scanning the article, it seems that the lede saying that this was "first described" by Hardin seems wrong. He was the first to use the term but that's different. How about replacing
- This dilemma was first described in an influential article titled "The Tragedy of the Commons," written by ecologist Garrett Hardin and first published in the journal Science in 1968.
with something along the lines of
- This dilemma has been recognized for many centuries, but the term "tragedy of the commons" was coined by ecologist Garrett Hardin as the title of an influential essay published in the journal Science in 1968.
I'm not a regular on this article so I'm not going to do this, but I'm suggesting it. Herostratus (talk) 04:17, 28 September 2011 (UTC)
Similarity to Prisoner's dilemma
I notice there is a strong similarity between Tragedy of the commons and the Prisoner's dilemma. Especially, it is obvious when comparing the "real-life examples". Maybe one could say that the tragedy of the common is a result of people acting rationally upon the prisoner's dilemma?
At least, I think the "See also" section should include a reference to the Prisoner's dilemma. CLHA (talk) 18:47, 4 October 2011 (UTC)
The Population Bomb
The Population Bomb was a book published the same year. Both the book and this article have the same concern, overpopulation. This article should mention the relationship between the book and Hardin's article. Which one of these was published first? They are both the same topic and very influential. Or was this general theme talked about that year?
It should also note the reasons why concerns about population control are reduced and that nowadays there is more in the media about preserving resources.
QuentinUK (talk) 17:58, 11 October 2011 (UTC)
- What are you suggesting is the connection between the two? Hardin's theory is
not about overpopulation but ratherabout how commonsspacesare used. Sunray (talk) 18:38, 11 October 2011 (UTC)- Have you read the essay? It's exactly about population. He just discusses land use as a metaphor or example of the problems he sees with unlimited reproduction. I can't answer QuentinUK's question (at least without doing research), but it's relevant. Will Beback talk 20:25, 11 October 2011 (UTC)
- I stand corrected. Though he only mentions overpopulation twice, his thesis is that: "abandoning the commons in [i.e., limiting] breeding," is necessary as there is no technical solution to "the misery of overpopulation." Sunray (talk) 06:13, 12 October 2011 (UTC)
- It's a common mistake. Naturally, this article focuses on the general issue rather than Hardin's specific concern. Will Beback talk 07:43, 12 October 2011 (UTC)
- I stand corrected. Though he only mentions overpopulation twice, his thesis is that: "abandoning the commons in [i.e., limiting] breeding," is necessary as there is no technical solution to "the misery of overpopulation." Sunray (talk) 06:13, 12 October 2011 (UTC)
- Have you read the essay? It's exactly about population. He just discusses land use as a metaphor or example of the problems he sees with unlimited reproduction. I can't answer QuentinUK's question (at least without doing research), but it's relevant. Will Beback talk 20:25, 11 October 2011 (UTC)
- [Journal of Comparative Family Studies]' first issues were published in 1970. This date, only two years after the publication of Paul Ehrlich's (1968) The Population Bomb and Garett Hardin's (1968) Tragedy of the Commons, marks the height of public and academic concerns about population growth and the threats it posed (e.g., Meadows et al. 1974).
- A Half Century of Fertility Change. Morgan, S Philip; Rackin, Heather. Journal of Comparative Family Studies 41. 4 (Summer 2010): 515-.
- Two seminal papers for contemporary food ethics are nearing their fortieth anniversary. ‘‘Famine, Affluence and Morality,’’ was one of several early papers that established the reputation of a young Australian philosopher named Peter Singer (1972), while ‘‘Lifeboat Ethics: The Case Against Helping the Poor,’’ was contributed by the ecologist Garrett Hardin (1974), already famous for his paper ‘‘The Tragedy of the Commons.’’ Both papers were published during a time when crushing famines were making headlines, and against the background of a freshly minted environmental consciousness sparked by books such as Paul Ehrlich’s The Population Bomb and Barry Commoner’s The Closing Circle. Singer argued for a moral obligation to feed starving people, while Hardin argued against it.
- Food Aid and the Famine Relief Argument (Brief Return) Thompson, Paul B. Journal of Agricultural and Environmental Ethics23. 3 (2010): 209-227.
- In his book "The Population Bomb," Mr. Ehrlich criticized DDT for being too effective in reducing death rates and thus contributing to "overpopulation." Hardin opposed spraying pesticides in the Third World because "every life saved this year in a poor country diminishes the quality of life for subsequent generations." For these activists, malaria was nature's way of controlling population growth, and DDT got in the way.
- DDT and Population Control. Editorial. Wall Street Journal [New York, N.Y] 24 Apr 2010: .12.
- The world’s population has increased dramatically since Thomas Malthus first proffered his rather gloomy prognostications on the matter. From an estimated one billion at the turn of the nineteenth century, human numbers grew to more than three billion by the 1960s, when Garrett Hardin and Paul Ehrlich rekindled Malthus’ fears with ominous predictions of food and land being despoiled by the teeming masses of people who held no regard for the rights or needs of others. Ehrlich wrote, for example, that ‘‘the battle to feed all of humanity is over…In the 1970s and 1980s hundreds of millions of people will starve to death’’ (Ehrlich 1968). Hardin maintained that the ‘‘goal of the greatest good for the greatest number’’ would be unobtainable in a world that grew beyond its optimum level of occupants (Hardin 1968). Arguing that families who do not face negative consequences for doing so will continue to produce children wantonly, Hardin appealed for the end of welfare supports that encourage ‘‘overbreeding,’’ just as Malthus called for the end of the British poor laws in 1798. Because individuals simply could not act in the best interests of society, it was incumbent upon the government to intervene to appropriately manage the commons. Malthus, Ehrlich and Hardin prioritized the values of survival, welfare and justice for the current and future global community over the value of individual freedom. In their very reductionistic consequentialist prescription, because the ends justify the means, the means; namely, restrictions on reproductive freedom, were therefore not only acceptable, they were ethically sound.
- Policy review: thoughts on addressing population and climate change in a just and ethical manner. Petroni, Suzanne. Population and Environment30. 6 (Jul 2009): 275-289.
And so on. The two publications are often compared and contrasted. But it'd be harder to answer QuentinUK's questions about how they came to be written in the same year, and which came first. Further research might turn up something. Will Beback talk 20:53, 11 October 2011 (UTC)
OR tag
Placed this tag after the last sentence of the intro to show that the sentence is out of place without a citation -- it makes a claim that merits citation. This likely could be fixed by moving the previous citation ahead to the end of the section, but since I'm not familiar with the sources, I used OR, and now here we are. Zach99998 (talk) 03:38, 14 October 2011 (UTC)
Relevant? Raj Patel's "The Value of Nothing"
- Raj Patel's "The Value of Nothing"?
The name of the book comes from a quotation from Oscar Wilde, "nowadays people know the price of everything and the value of nothing". The book is about the food politics: how market forces cause poverty and starvation. 99.181.142.231 (talk) 05:29, 17 January 2012 (UTC)
- It's not for us to decide if it's relevant. Either the work itself needs to discuss this topic, or some 3rd party needs to make the connection. Will Beback talk 19:35, 17 January 2012 (UTC)
No mentions of externalities
I think it is at least worth mentioning externalities in this context. Even if the argument is pushed that the tragedy of the commons is not a form of an externality (which I think is rather silly, but I'm willing to hear it) it still doesn't explain the lack of any reference to this deeply related concept. Walras101 (talk) 23:53, 26 February 2012 (UTC)
- Some extra explanation sounds like a good idea. They're clearly related concepts. bobrayner (talk) 01:01, 27 February 2012 (UTC)
Tradegy of Internet Commons
Assuming WP:RS can be found, it would be a fascinating add to this article to discuss the trashing of Commons on the Internet. This includes spam across the Internet, but also the hijacking of sites for purposes other than that of their "owners" and supporters. Wikipedia itself is such a commons, not just for vandalism and other spam, but all the marketing and other non-encyclopedic text and articles that have been added. Lentower (talk) 14:38, 17 June 2012 (UTC)
Private Property Solves All Problems?
I don't get it: how can the tenor of this article be that privatization solves the Tragedy of the Commons when we see mass deforestation and other non-sustainable use of private property all over the place? I can see no imperative to use private property sustainably. However, such an imperative is implied all over this article. --Mudd1 (talk) 12:13, 24 September 2012 (UTC)
Popcorn and Mortgage Rates?
What about commercial things that people buy being a tragedy of the commons? Like if no one paid $10 for a bag of popcorn at the movies, then popcorn wouldn't be priced at $10. Similarly, if the maximum home loan that could be given was 10 years (or no one took out a home loan over 10 years), then housing prices would be less, and people would own their homes sooner. Allowing for longer terms just allows for more competition. Someone who makes xxx dollars and wants to pay off a house with a 10 year loan now has to compete with someone else making significantly less who wants to buy the same place on a 30 or 40 year loan, and this additional competition drives prices up. — Preceding unsigned comment added by 198.182.9.80 (talk) 16:40, 11 October 2012 (UTC)
I suggest that any meat (pun related to grazing cows was not originally noted, but seems appropriate) from Concentrated benefits and diffuse costs be merged here, near Walter Williams's note on grazing politicians. Same tragedy, different POV. Yes, I did suggest that the article be deleted, and I still don't see the topic as yet notable or the term commonly used, but notability is not required for a section of an article, if it's relevant. — Arthur Rubin (talk) 20:56, 15 December 2012 (UTC)
Can you provide any reliable sources that establish a connection between the two concepts? Here are some of the reliable sources that I've found...none of which mention a connection between the two concepts...
- Coleman, John - Democracy's Debt Dilemma Harvard Business Review. 24 April 2012
- Farber, Daniel A. and O'Connell, Anne Joseph - Research Handbook on Public Choice and Public Law 2010
- Schneider, Friedrich and Rowley, Charles Kershaw - The Encyclopedia of Public Choice 2004
- Olson, Mancur - The Logic of Collective Action. Harvard University Press. 1971
- Taylor, John B. and Weerapana, Akila - Principles of Microeconomics 2009
- Nechyba, Thomas - Microeconomics: An Intuitive Approach 2010
- Persson, Torsten and Tabellini, Guido Enrico - Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy 2000
- Tomasi, John - Free Market Fairness 2012
- Public Choice: Why Politicians Don't Cut Spending. LearnLiberty.org. 20 April 2011
- Boaz, David - Well Worth the Money. Cato. 22 Aug 2011
- Boaz, David - What Big Government Is All About The Freeman.
- Ikeda, Sandy - Two Kinds of Government Failure The Freeman.
- Giberson, Michael - Concentrated benefits and dispersed costs
--Xerographica (talk) 01:24, 24 December 2012 (UTC)
- Can you provide any evidence that it is not the same as Walter Williams's concept in this article. — Arthur Rubin (talk) 01:08, 26 December 2012 (UTC)
- Please quote exactly which passage from Williams's article Tragedy of unbridled self-interest leads you to believe that he's talking about the concept of concentrated benefits and diffuse costs. "Diffuse costs" means that it's not worth it for the 100,000,000 million taxpayers who each pay $1 for a sugar subsidy to make the effort to lobby against it. The benefits are concentrated on a small group of sugar farmers while the costs are dispersed among millions of taxpayers. Even if taxpayers weren't rationally ignorant...they would still be rationally inactive. It's not the "commons" because there is only cost, and absolutely no benefit, for the taxpayers. Therefore, it's legal plunder...a small group of sugar farmers "legally" reach into all our pockets and take out $1. Again, please thoroughly research topics BEFORE you edit them. This is now the third time that I've told you this. --Xerographica (talk) 02:43, 26 December 2012 (UTC)
- Whether or not you know what you're talking about (which I doubt), you have not written a word which is helpful for Wikipedia. Please do not write "articles" until you have something sourced to reliable sources. I think I lean back toward delete, again. — Arthur Rubin (talk) 03:47, 26 December 2012 (UTC)
- I've shared numerous reliable sources (see above) but you clearly have no interest in reading them. The problem isn't lack of RS...here are 38 search results from the FEE.org website alone...the problem is that you have absolutely no interest in the topic. Why not just edit the entries that interest you? Right now you are contributing absolutely nothing of value to the editing process...you're just wasting my time. --Xerographica (talk) 04:14, 26 December 2012 (UTC)
- Based on your failure to provide a single RS that supports your argument, I'm going to redirect CB/DC to legal plunder. --Xerographica (talk) 18:58, 28 December 2012 (UTC)
Legal plunder
This one, also. It's obviously the same concept, and there is absolutely no possible reason for creating creating two articles about the same concept. — Arthur Rubin (talk) 01:08, 26 December 2012 (UTC)
- This one might be transwikied to Wiktionary, rather than, or in addition to, merging to Tragedy of the commons. — Arthur Rubin (talk) 01:26, 26 December 2012 (UTC)
- Xerographica, it appears that after Wikipedia:Articles for deletion/Concentrated benefits and diffuse costs was closed as "redirect", you recreated most of the content at Legal plunder. Mostly quotes which do not actually mention legal plunder. Why did you do this? bobrayner (talk) 19:05, 28 December 2012 (UTC)
- Wikipedia is not a dictionary. The term "legal plunder" is not the focus of the entry...the concept is. How can you edit Wikipedia without understanding that the concept, and not the term itself, is the focus of entries? It would be one thing if you had said that some of the passages focused on completely different concepts...but the only thing you did was read them over to see if they actually used the term "legal plunder". If you want to make helpful, useful and beneficial contributions to an entry...then you have to actually understand the concept. Otherwise you're just going to be a VDE. I understand the concepts because I've thoroughly read countless reliable sources. Please do the same...and then come back with some insight into where there's room for improvement. --Xerographica (talk) 19:29, 28 December 2012 (UTC)
- Xerographica, it appears that after Wikipedia:Articles for deletion/Concentrated benefits and diffuse costs was closed as "redirect", you recreated most of the content at Legal plunder. Mostly quotes which do not actually mention legal plunder. Why did you do this? bobrayner (talk) 19:05, 28 December 2012 (UTC)
Allan Savory's pet theory
The last paragraph in the Criticism section is a tangent on the grazing habits of cattle. Hardin used 'cows on the commons' as analogy to explain the relationship between individual benefit and shared cost. The last paragraph presents some jumble about herd behavior and soil moisture, which completely misses the point of the analogy and nitpicks an obviously simplified thought experiment. I would venture that some advocate of Allan Savory's 'Holistic Grazing' added this last paragraph to further this fringe theory on the literal management of cows. The criticisms presented in the last paragraph are scientifically unsound and, even worse, completely irrelevant. I say delete it. — Preceding unsigned comment added by 128.84.127.236 (talk) 18:51, 25 March 2013 (UTC)
17?
"Referring to Hardin's crucial passage on page 1244,17 Partha Dasgupta, for example, comments that 'it is difficult to find a passage of comparable length and fame that contains so many errors as the one quoted.'[16] " First, the link, despite its label in the footnote, does not take us to this passage at all. Second, what does "on page 1244, 17 Partha Dasgupta," mean? In particular, what is the 17?Kdammers (talk) 04:43, 3 April 2013 (UTC)
Econ 101 vs. culture wars
I just edited the lede to reduce gross overreliance on Hardin. The article seems to be caught in culture wars and needs a lot more work, that I don't have the time to do. This is a very basic economics concept, that apparently Hardin popularized among the ecological community. I learned about this concept years ago--its basic in economics 101 and economic history courtses--yet never heard of Hardin til today. The history section could be expanded to Adam Smith's Moral Theory book, or to George Orwell or even Gifford Pinchot, but the commons tragedy concept was very well known long before Hardin, so this does not really need to be a memorial page for him. I left the Partha Dasgupta cite in, without checking it, because he seems to be one of the critics or commentatators on Hardin, and even that section seemed to be a rehash of Hardin's work. IMHO, wikipedia's not meant to be a rehash, but a gathering place or even a jumping-off-place for scholarly research. But right now, the article's too messy to do that. Jweaver28 (talk) 16:12, 23 April 2013 (UTC)
- The tragedy of the commons is not just an economics topic, and contrary to what you were taught Hardin is highly relevant. The courses you studied must indeed have been 101. Over half of the 45,000 articles listed by Google Scholar which mention the topic also mention Hardin. As Hardin puts it, the tragedy of the commons has "been included in anthologies on ecology, environmentalism, health care, economics, population studies, law, political science, philosophy, ethics, geography, psychology, and sociology". It is a wide spectrum topic, and is as much about ideology and politics as it is about science or economics. --Epipelagic (talk) 20:14, 25 September 2013 (UTC)
Protection
I've just fully protected this article for three days due to the edit warring. Please discuss the matter here on the talk page instead of continually reverting. Mark Arsten (talk) 19:04, 24 September 2013 (UTC)
- Chomsky's no economist, but he's published an immense amount on the politically motivated, deliberate twisting of meanings of terms from many fields. When blurred meanings confuse public debate (the common assertion, contrary to Radkau) it's worth noting. Attleboro (talk) 19:16, 24 September 2013 (UTC)
- In what way could Chomsky ever be considered a reliable source on this topic? bobrayner (talk) 01:19, 25 September 2013 (UTC)
- You say, bobrayner, in an edit summary that "wikipedia is supposed to represent reliable sources and the mainstream view". What is the "mainstream view" of the tragedy of the commons, and how do you know it is the mainstream view? And how would you identify what you consider to be reliable sources in this context? Why would you regard the libertarian views of the Austrian School economist Ludwig von Mises as relevant and reliable, and yet disregard the views of the renowned linguist and intellectual Chomsky on the use of the term? --Epipelagic (talk) 03:32, 25 September 2013 (UTC)
- I'm biased toward the Austrian School, but Chomsky is not an expert on much of anything, except in his own mind. — Arthur Rubin (talk) 09:17, 26 September 2013 (UTC)
- Thinking about it, Chomsky is an expert on politically motivated, deliberate twisting of meanings. He's done enough of it to know. — Arthur Rubin (talk) 09:18, 26 September 2013 (UTC)
- You say, bobrayner, in an edit summary that "wikipedia is supposed to represent reliable sources and the mainstream view". What is the "mainstream view" of the tragedy of the commons, and how do you know it is the mainstream view? And how would you identify what you consider to be reliable sources in this context? Why would you regard the libertarian views of the Austrian School economist Ludwig von Mises as relevant and reliable, and yet disregard the views of the renowned linguist and intellectual Chomsky on the use of the term? --Epipelagic (talk) 03:32, 25 September 2013 (UTC)
- In what way could Chomsky ever be considered a reliable source on this topic? bobrayner (talk) 01:19, 25 September 2013 (UTC)
- Yes, I gather Chomsky upsets you Arthur, and you don't want him mentioned in the article. But as far as I am aware you are not a notable expert in the field yourself, so we cannot use you as a reliable source for the article. Chomsky's views are at least as influential as von Mises's. There are many takes on the tragedy of the commons, as mentioned in the previous thread above, and the article should aim to present these with a measure of balance. --Epipelagic (talk) 10:29, 26 September 2013 (UTC)
- I'm sure you can find expert comments on this subject. Chomsky is not an expert, but perhaps his opinions should be reported as personal opinions if notable. I don't think they are notable, but I could be convinced by adequate citations. — Arthur Rubin (talk) 14:31, 26 September 2013 (UTC)
- If Chomsky were "not an expert on much of anything, except in his own mind", he would not have such a massive life work of academic publications. He could hardly have paid for all that himself. He is, in fact, an expert on deliberate and self-serving misuse of language and, so, is qualified to speak, and be heard, wherever germane. Attleboro (talk) 21:12, 26 September 2013 (UTC)
- Chomsky's academic work is impressive (although far from uncontroversial), but this is not an article about linguistics and grammar. Chomsky's lengthy comments on economics and geopolitics are not the kind of thing we should spread further. bobrayner (talk) 04:42, 27 September 2013 (UTC)
- I agree "lengthy comments" from Chomsky don't belong in the article, but no one is suggesting that. However, as a prominent linguist and commentator on the political use of language, a salient point from him on widespread ideological misuses of the term "tragedy of the commons" is certainly appropriate. Would you mind answering the questions I addressed to you above? --Epipelagic (talk) 07:53, 27 September 2013 (UTC)
- Chomsky's academic work is impressive (although far from uncontroversial), but this is not an article about linguistics and grammar. Chomsky's lengthy comments on economics and geopolitics are not the kind of thing we should spread further. bobrayner (talk) 04:42, 27 September 2013 (UTC)
- If Chomsky were "not an expert on much of anything, except in his own mind", he would not have such a massive life work of academic publications. He could hardly have paid for all that himself. He is, in fact, an expert on deliberate and self-serving misuse of language and, so, is qualified to speak, and be heard, wherever germane. Attleboro (talk) 21:12, 26 September 2013 (UTC)
- I'm sure you can find expert comments on this subject. Chomsky is not an expert, but perhaps his opinions should be reported as personal opinions if notable. I don't think they are notable, but I could be convinced by adequate citations. — Arthur Rubin (talk) 14:31, 26 September 2013 (UTC)
Modern solutions: Cooperation to conserve resources?
Under the heading 'Modern solutions', the following text can be found: "Alternatively, resource users themselves can cooperate to conserve the resource in the name of mutual benefit." To my mind, however, this leads straight into the tragedy of the commons due to the free-rider problem. Instead, policy-based solutions are required. Therefore, I recommend removing this sentence. Musicnut83 (talk) 00:46, 29 October 2013 (UTC)