Predatory pricing

(Redirected from Price dumping)

Predatory pricing is a commercial pricing strategy which involves the use of large scale undercutting to eliminate competition. This is where an industry dominant firm with sizable market power will deliberately reduce the prices of a product or service to loss-making levels to attract all consumers and create a monopoly.[1] For a period of time, the prices are set unrealistically low to ensure competitors are unable to effectively compete with the dominant firm without making substantial loss. The aim is to force existing or potential competitors within the industry to abandon the market so that the dominant firm may establish a stronger market position and create further barriers to entry.[2] Once competition has been driven from the market, consumers are forced into a monopolistic market where the dominant firm can safely increase prices to recoup its losses.[3]

The critical difference between predatory pricing and other market strategies is the potential for consumer harm in the long-term. Despite initial buyer's market created through firms' competing for consumer preference, as the price war favours the dominant firm, consumers will be forced to accept fewer options and higher prices for the same goods and services in the monopolistic market.[4] If strategy is successful, predatory pricing can cause consumer harm and is, therefore, considered anti-competitive in many jurisdictions making the practice illegal under numerous competition laws.

Concept

edit

Predatory pricing is split into a two-stage strategy.

The first stage of predatory pricing (predation) involves the dominant firm offering goods and services at below-cost rate which, in turn, leads to a reduction in the firm's immediate short-term profits. This drop in price forces the market price for those goods or services to readjust to this lower price, putting smaller firms and industry entrants at risk of exiting the industry. The principle behind this strategy is that, unlike new entrants and current players, the dominant firm has the size and capital to sustain short-term loss in profits, thus forcing a game of survival that the dominant firm is likely to win.[5]

The second stage is the recoupment, during which the dominant firm readjusts its product and service prices to approach monopoly prices (or a monopoly price, depending on remaining industry players and the dominant firm's market share) to recover their losses in the long-term. This price adjustment can put consumers under pressure, as they are now forced to accept the higher price without any fair-priced competition, thus resulting in consumer harm. This is what differentiates predatory pricing from normal competitive pricing.[6] Under EU law, the European Commission can account for recoupment as a factor when determining whether predatory pricing is abusive.[7] This is because predatory pricing can only be considered economically effective if a firm can recover its short-term losses from pricing below Average Variable Costs (AVC).[8] However, recoupment is not a precondition for establishing whether predatory pricing is an abuse of dominance under Article 102 TFEU.[9] Assessing other factors, such as barriers to entry, can suffice in demonstrating how predatory pricing can lead to foreclosure of competitors from the market.[10]

The use of predatory pricing to gain a foothold in a market in one territory while maintaining high prices in the suppliers' home market (also known as "dumping") creates a risk that the loss-making product will find its way back to the home market and drive down prices there. This can result in negative effects on the home market and cause harm to domestic supplies and producers. Due to this, countries often have laws and regulations enforced to prevent dumping and other forms of predatory pricing strategies that may distort trade.[11]

edit

1. The principal aspect of predatory pricing is that the seller in the market has a certain economic or technical strength which distinguishes it from price discrimination, where competition exists amongst both buyers and sellers.

2. The geographic market for predatory pricing is the country's domestic market which differentiates it from "dumping". Dumping refers to the practice of selling commodities in overseas markets at a lower price than within the domestic market. Though it can be determined that both concepts have similarities in terms of "low-cost sales" and "exhaustion of competitors", numerous differences have been noted:

(1) The scopes of application of the two are different. Predatory pricing applies to domestic trade, while dumping applies to international trade.

(2) The identification standards of the two are different. Predatory pricing is based on cost, while dumping is based on the price applicable to the normal trading of similar domestic products.

(3) The laws applicable to both are different. Predatory pricing mainly falls under domestic laws, while dumping falls to international treaties or the laws of other countries.

(4) The consequences of the two are different. Legal sanctions for predatory pricing are compensatory damages or administrative penalties, while dumping involves the levying of anti-dumping duties.

3. The objective performance of predatory pricing is that a company temporarily sells goods or services below cost to eliminate competitors from a certain market and create exclusivity. The predatory pricing company can then sell goods and services at monopoly prices to compensate for the losses from initial low price sales.

4. A dominant firm's subjective intention may be to eliminate competition to gain a monopoly advantage. Under EU law, if a dominant firm prices above AVC but below Average Total Costs (ATC), proving intention can be useful evidence for finding predatory pricing.[12] However, the difficulty is faced when distinguishing between an intention to eliminate competitors and an intention to win the competition.[13] Thus, the European Commission does not have to establish an undertaking's subjective intention to prove that Article 102 applies, as abuse is an objective rather than a subjective concept.[14]

Implementation conditions

edit

1. Sacrificing short-term profits

The economic theory of predatory pricing involves a company pricing its goods and services to generate less revenue in the short term, thus, eliminating competitors and increasing market power. The theory does not explicitly state that profits must be negative in order for this to be achieved. In anti-monopoly law enforcement, determining the level of pricing that constitutes predatory pricing can be difficult in operation. The generally acceptable standard is that during a period of predatory prices, the predator's profit will be negative where the price is lower than the initial cost. However, with this the question arises as to what kind of cost should be used as a reference. The use of a price that is lower than the cost may make certain predatory pricing practices not legally binding.

According to the theory of industrial organization, some predatory pricing practices may not necessarily lead to negative short-term profits. However, in this particular case, the company's ability to make low-cost profits can indicate that the company is a highly efficient company compared to its competitors. This does not necessarily indicate that such instances will lead to reduced benefits in the long-term as non-entry of entrants does not necessarily reduce welfare, and entry of entrants does not necessarily improve it. Consequently, anti-monopoly law ignores this and does not result in major welfare losses.[15]

2. The ability of incumbent company to raise prices

An important condition for predatory pricing is that, after excluding competitors, a dominant firm can raise prices to compensate for their short-term losses. To achieve this, market power can be an important factor. However, under EU law, market power is not necessary to establish predatory pricing,[16] since other factors such as barriers to entry can indicate an abuse of a dominant position.[10]

It is also important to note the barriers to entry impact on a dominant firm's ability to raise the price of their goods and services. On the exclusion of these barriers, other firms could theoretically enter any market where an incumbent firm is enjoying economic profits, thereby preventing the dominant firm from sufficiently raising prices high enough to recoup the costs of lowering price.

Theories for controlling predatory pricing

edit

It can be difficult to identify when normal price competition turns into anti-competitive predatory pricing.[17] Therefore, various rules and economic tests have been established to identify predatory pricing.

No rule

edit

According to Easterbrook, predatory pricing is rare and should not be considered a central concern. Introducing laws against predation, especially because it is rare, could lead to generating false positive errors, which would restrict the rule. The main point of the argument is that government intervention is dispensable, as predation is unlikely to succeed and creates a deterrent effect on its own. The deterrent effect results from selling goods and services below the costs, which causes losses without the gain in market power. In this case, the market power does not increase due to the market share holder weathering the predatory strategy. Thus, the firm punished itself by taking losses without gaining market share. As a consequence, this acts a deterrent for other firms. An additional argument against the implementation of rules is the inability of courts or competition authorities to differentiate predatory from competitive prices.[18]

Short-term loss rules and the Areeda-Turner test

edit

In 1975, Phillip Areeda and Donald Turner developed a short-run cost-based test, widely referred to as the 'Areeda-Turner rule'.[19] The rules are based on short term focus due to the long run focus being too speculative and inefficient. The Areeda-Turner rule suggests prices at or above reasonable expected average variable costs (AVC) are presumed to be lawful, but prices below AVC are presumed to be unlawful and anti-competitive.[19]

In EU law, the approach to testing for predatory pricing under Article 102 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU) has been explained in a number of important cases.

In ECS/AKZO, the European Commission did not adopt the Areeda-Turner rule.[20] The Court of Justice upheld this decision for the inclusion of other factors (such as proof of intention to eliminate competition) to be taken into consideration alongside a cost-based analysis.[21] Instead, the Court in AKZO suggested that if a dominant firm sets prices below AVC, the predatory pricing is presumed to be abusively predatory due to the assumed intention to eliminate competitors rather than maximize profits.[8] However, a strategy would not be presumed predatory were a dominant firm to set prices above AVC but below ATC unless evidence were provided to show dominant firm's plan to eliminate competition.[12] Additionally, if a dominant firm sets prices above ATC, the firm is most commonly not found guilty of predatory pricing, though, still may be proven anti-competitive if potential for substantial consumer harm is discovered.[22] The AKZO test was reaffirmed in Tetra Pak II,[23] and France Télécom.[24]

In Post Danmark I, the Court of Justice developed upon AKZO by stating that prices above average incremental costs but below ATC would not likely be ruled abusive under Article 102 of the TFEU if there was no evidence the dominant firm deliberately intended to eliminate competition.[25]

Long-term cost-based rule

edit

Posner's long-term cost-based rule assumes that long-run marginal costs are a more reliable test of predation than short-run costs. This is due to the predator, who prices at short-run marginal cost, having the ability to eliminate competitors that cannot afford the same losses in the short-run. To determine predation, Posner brought forth a test that substitutes the average costs from the firm's balance sheet to establish a test that relates to the full average costs based on the company's books. The test would include certain prerequisites, an intent element, as well as a defense. As a prerequisite, Posner requires the plaintiff to demonstrate that the market was predestined for effective predatory pricing.[26] As indicators, Posner lists, for instance, that the predator operates in various markets, whereas the prey operates in fewer markets, concentrated markets, slow entry, few fringe firms, homogenous products and numerous buyers. Posner would authorize the firm to defend due to changes in supply or demand, allowing the respondent firm to price its products at short-run marginal cost.[27]

According to the European Commission's "Guidance on the Commission's Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the Treaty to Abusive Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings", if a dominant firm does not cover its average avoidable costs or long-run average incremental costs, this implies the dominant firm is operating at a loss in the short-term to foreclose equally efficient competitors from the market.[28] The Guidance does not bind the EU Courts,[29] however, it is an important document that could influence future decisions.[30]

Rules governing price increases after predation

edit

William Baumol proposed a long-term rule seeking to avoid full reliance on cost-based tests to determine predatory pricing.[31] Baumol's rule involves requiring any price cut made in response to entry to continue for a five-year period after the exit of the entrant (i.e., if an incumbent firm cuts its price to drive out an entrant, the incumbent firm is prevented from increasing price for five years).[32] This rule significantly diminishes the incentive of a firm to engage in predatory pricing since the predatory firm cannot reap the benefits of its anti-competitive behavior (monopoly profits) during the five-year period. Baumol's proposed rule is not absolute, however, it does offer the predator some freedom to raise its post-exit price if the price increase is justified by demonstrable changes in the firm's costs or market demand.[33]

Further strategies

edit

Industry-specific rules

edit

Craswell and Fratrik suggest that establishing a legal standard to detect predatory pricing in the retail industry is unnecessary and should not amount to an antitrust violation. The primary reasoning was that predatory pricing typically requires strong barriers to entry to generate profits in the long run, which are absent in the retail grocery industry.[34] When low-cost warehouse stores enter the market, supermarkets often reduce their prices to eliminate this competition or discourage them from expansion. However, Craswell and Fratrik suggest that this may not be predatory pricing, but rather incumbent firms engaging in non-predatory price cuts required for ordinary competition.[35]

Rule of reason test

edit

Section 1 of the Sherman Act Antitrust Act of 1890 prohibits 'every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce.' However, Courts have adopted the rule of reason test to analyze the effects of a restraint of trade on competition. Recent case law suggests that there is a four-step rule of reason test.[36] First, the plaintiff must demonstrate an "anti-competitive effect". Second, the defendant must show a "legitimate procompetitive justification". Third, the plaintiff must highlight that the restraint is not "reasonably necessary" to achieve the defendant's objectives or that there are "less restrictive alternatives". Fourth, the Court will balance the restraint of trade's "anti-competitive effects with its pro-competitive justifications."[37] Failure to satisfy any of these elements will defeat the anti-trust violation claim.

Output restriction rule

edit

Williamson offers the output restriction rule to restrain dominant firms from engaging in predatory pricing. The rule stipulates that upon the entry of a new firm in a market, a dominant firm cannot abuse their position by increasing their output above the pre-entry level.[38] A prevention period of 12 to 18 months should be adequate for new entrants to establish a market identity and understand economies of scale while disincentivizing dominant firms from holding excess capacity.[38] Williamson suggests that the output restriction rule possesses greater welfare properties than the short-run marginal cost rule or short-run average cost rule.[39]

Two tier approach

edit

Joskow and Klevorick offer a two-tier approach to identify predatory pricing. The first stage involves an analysis of the structural characteristics of the relevant market and the market power of the firm allegedly engaging in anti-competitive behaviour.[40] The plaintiff must demonstrate that the market in which the behaviour occurred would be prone to predatory pricing and cause losses in economic efficiency. The second stage involves behavioural considerations which may demonstrate predation such as the dominant firm pricing below average variable cost.[40]

The Brooke Group rule

The Brooke Group rule was established by the US Supreme Court in 1993 for the particular case involving Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corporation. Under this rule, to be found guilty of predatory pricing, the plaintiff was to prove the following:

  1. Defendant set prices to below own cost of production.
  2. If successful in driving competitors from the market, defendant had high probability of recouping losses through increase in prices in the long-term.
  3. Defendant had clear intent to engage in predatory pricing

The first element can be proven with sufficient evidence of defendant's costs in the production of their goods and services. The second element can be proven with evidence of the defendant's barriers to entry, market power and other evidence that would likely lead to the increase in prices in the future. The third element would require direct evidence to clearly demonstrate the defendant's plans to manipulate the market through use of predatory pricing strategy. This may be found through capture of firm's internal documents or plans.[41]

If all elements can be proven with sufficient evidence for each, following the Brooke Group rule, the plaintiff may claim for predatory pricing under the US antitrust law.[42]

edit

In many countries, there are legal restrictions upon using the predatory pricing strategy as it may be deemed anti-competitive. Although it may not be technically illegal, it can be subject to severe restrictions.

Australia

edit

Predatory pricing is illegal in Australia under the Competition and Consumer Act 2010 (formally known as the Trade Practices Act).[43] The Act prohibits the use of this particular commercial strategy by dominant firms with significant quantity of the market share within the industry of operation. The Act defines the strategy as a dominant firm employing the method of undercutting or underselling with the intention to force competitors to exit or prevent entry to the industry. The dominant firm can only have significant quantity of the market share in an industry if the firm is not substantially impacted or constrained by its competitors on suppliers and consumers.[44]

In 2017, the Australian government amended the Competition and Consumer Act by introducing an "effects test". This particular test determined engagement in predatory pricing if a firm were discovered to be selling goods or services at prices likely to lead to the lessening of competition in a market industry. This amendment to the Act was one of the changes included in the "Harper reforms" that expanded the predatory pricing definition to include the effect of below-cost prices in lessening competition regardless of firm market power. The Harper reforms were introduced to allow for smaller firms to stand ground amongst larger firms engaging in predatory behaviour and anti-competitive strategies.[45]

In 2020, further amendments to the Act created a new threshold test to prohibit those engaging in predatory pricing and strengthen the prohibition of market power misuse. These amendments were made in response to the recommendations made during the Harper reforms. The amendments, labelled the "Birdsville Amendments" after Senator Barnaby Joyce, penned the idea[46] in Section 46, to define the practice more liberally than other behavior by requiring the business to first have a "substantial share of a market" (rather than substantial market power). This was made in a move to further protect smaller businesses from larger players and their misuse of market power.

Canada

edit

Section 50 of the Competition Act, which criminalized predatory pricing, has been repealed[47] and replaced by sections 78 and 79, which both deal with the matters civilly.

Section 78(1)(i)[48] of the Competition Act prohibits companies from the selling of products at unreasonably low prices designed to facilitate the effect of eliminating competition or a competitor. The Competition Bureau has established Predatory Pricing Guidelines defining what is considered unreasonably low pricing.

United States

edit

Predatory pricing practices may result in antitrust claims of monopolization or attempts to monopolize. Businesses with dominant or substantial market shares are more susceptible to antitrust claims. However, as antitrust laws are ultimately intended to benefit consumers, and discounting results in at least short-term net benefit to consumers, the U.S. Supreme Court has set high hurdles to antitrust claims based on predatory pricing theory. The Court requires plaintiffs to show a likelihood that the pricing practices affect not only rivals, but also competition in the market as a whole in order to establish there is a substantial probability of success in monopolization.[49] If there is a likelihood that market entrants will prevent the predator from recouping its investment through supra-competitive pricing, then there is no probability of success and the antitrust claim would fail. Additionally, the Court established that for prices to be predatory, they must be below the seller's cost.

The US Department of Justice, however, argues that modern economic theory based on strategic analysis supports predatory pricing as a real problem, and claims that the courts are out of date and too skeptical.[50]

European Union

edit

Article 102 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union is the relevant statutory provision under EU law for dealing with predatory pricing. According to Article 102:

"Any abuse by one or more undertakings of a dominant position within the internal market or in a substantial part of it shall be prohibited as incompatible with the internal market in so far as it may affect trade between Member States." [51]

If Article 102 is breached by a predatory pricing practice, the European Commission may intervene as they prioritize dealing with "exclusionary abuses" which exclude competitors from the market.[52]  According to the 'Guidance in Applying Article 102', the Commission normally intervene in possible predatory pricing cases if a dominant firm aims to maintain or strengthen its market power by "sacrificing" short-term losses to foreclose "as efficient" competitors,[53] or even "less efficient" competitors.[54] The "as efficient competitor" refers to a hypothetical competitor with the same costs as the dominant firm.[55] The "as efficient competitor" test was endorsed in AKZO as the legal standard for assessing predatory pricing under Article 102.[12]

India

edit

The Competition Act, 2002 outlaws predatory pricing, treating it as an abuse of dominant position, prohibited under Section 4. Predatory pricing under the Act means the sale of goods or provision of services, at a price below cost, as may be determined by regulations, of production of the goods or provision of services, with a view to reduce competition or eliminate the competitors.[56] A contravention of section 4 of the Act is anti-competitive per se, where there is no requirement to prove that the conduct had an anti-competitive effect on the market.[57]

Russian Federation

edit

Article 10 of the Federal Law No.135-FZ 'On the Protection of Competition' (FLPC) (Russian: ст. 10, Федерального закона от 26.07.2006 N 135-ФЗ "О защите конкуренции") deals with unilateral conduct of economic entities by prohibiting abuse of dominant position. The definition of such abuse, as stated in the article, includes "the setting of an unjustified high or unjustified low price of a financial service by a financial entity".[58]

All the matters connected with the abuse of the market power are handled by the Federal Antimonopoly Service of Russian Federation (FAS). The FAS investigates all alleged violations of the antimonopoly legislation and determines whether a dominant position has been exploited by one of the market participants.

United Kingdom

edit

Section 18(1) of the Competition Act 1998 prohibits the abuse of a dominant position by "one or more undertakings... if it may affect trade within the United Kingdom."[59] This is commonly known as the "Chapter II prohibition". The section is very similar to article 102 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union governing the anti-monopoly laws within the EU jurisdiction, with the exception of parts regarding the effect on trade within the UK.

Germany

edit

Sections 19 and 20 of the Act against Restraints of Competition (ARC) prohibit the abuse of a dominant position. Section 19 lists in more detail the entities with market power addressed by the Act. Article 102 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union also applies, although it has some differences with the ARC.

Compliance with the Act is enforced by the German Federal Cartel Office (FCO) (German: Bundeskartellamt). With the FCO as the higher federal authority, there also exists state cartels in each of the federal states in Germany. The FCO is in the area of responsibility of the Federal Ministry for Economic Affairs and Energy (German: Bundesministerium für Wirtschaft und Energie).

Austria

edit

The European competition law art. 82 EC and § 5 KartG 2005 prohibit a market dominant enterprise, as well as a collective of several dominant enterprises, from intentionally suppressing a competitor or increasing their respective market share by using methods other than those of legal competitive performance.[60] According to the law, predatory pricing is considered a violation if a market-dominant enterprise controls the local market by offering its goods and services at prices below AVC. However, if prices are below ATC, but above AVC, predattory pricing may not be considered a law violation. Furthermore, if market abuse is directed against competitors, and not against suppliers and clients, Austrian law provides provisions under § 1UWG (in connection with §5 para. 1 KartG 2005, if there is a competitive relationship).[61] Additionally, according to §1UWG, predatory pricing can be unconscionable if intended to harm competitors—even without the dominant company incurring losses. Moreover, predatory pricing can be unconscionable according to §1UWG if the dominant firm expels enough competitors from the market to gain enough market share to dictate prices.[62]

Denmark

edit

According to §6, sec. 1, of the Competition Act (CA), entering into anti-competitive agreements is prohibited. The CA §6 corresponds to art. 81, sec. 1 of the EC- Treaty and prohibits predatory pricing.[63]

Greece

edit

Generally, Art. 1(1) of the antitrust law (I. 703/1977) prohibits all agreements between undertakings, decisions by associations of undertakings and concerted practices that strive to prevent, restrict, or distort competition in the Greek market.[64] Particularly art. 2(1) of I 703/77 prohibits predatory pricing within Greece.

Sweden

edit

Under Art. 101 TFEU and Section 6 of the Swedish Competition Act (KL), agreements between undertakings with objectives to effect prevention, distortion or restriction of competition are strictly prohibited in Sweden. Price-fixing agreements (where competitors concur to set prices at an agreed level) between competitors are considered "hardcore" restriction of competition and are prohibited. This does not include other types of price agreements between competitors. These agreements may, therefore, be assessed under rule of reason and can be found permissible if no significant anti-competitive effects are identified.[65]

Criticism

edit

According to economist Thomas DiLorenzo, true predatory pricing is a rare phenomenon and an irrational practice with laws designed to inhibit competition.[66] According to the European Commission, this is because predatory pricing can cause firms to make a loss due to increased output.[10] This stance was taken by the US Supreme Court in the 1993 case Brooke Group v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco. The Federal Trade Commission has not successfully prosecuted any company for predatory pricing since.

Thomas Sowell explains one reason why predatory pricing may not be completely effective:

Obviously, predatory pricing pays off only if the surviving predator can then raise prices enough to recover the previous losses, making enough extra profit thereafter to justify the risks. These risks are not small.
However, even the demise of a competitor does not leave the survivor home free. Bankruptcy does not by itself destroy the fallen competitor's physical plant or the people whose skills made it a viable business. Both may be available-perhaps at distress prices-to others who can spring up to take the defunct firm's place.
The Washington Post went bankrupt in 1933, though not because of predatory pricing. But neither its physical plant, its people, or its name disappeared into thin air. Instead, publisher Eugene Meyer acquired all three-at a fraction of what he had bid unsuccessfully for the same newspaper just four years earlier. In the course of time, the Post became the biggest newspaper in Washington.[67]

Critics of laws against predatory pricing may support their case empirically by arguing that there has been no instance where such a practice has actually led to a monopoly.[68] Conversely, they argue that there is much evidence that predatory pricing has failed miserably. For example, Herbert Dow not only found a cheaper way to produce bromine but also defeated a predatory pricing attempt by the government-supported German cartel Bromkonvention, who objected to his selling in Germany at a lower price. Bromkonvention retaliated by flooding the US market with below-cost bromine, at an even lower price than Dow's. However, Dow simply instructed his agents to buy up at the very low price and then sell it back in Germany at a price still lower than Bromkonvention's. In the end, the cartel could not keep up with selling below cost and had to surrender in the price war. This was used as evidence that the free market is a better way to stop predatory pricing than regulations such as anti-trust laws.

In another example of a successful defense against predatory pricing, a price war emerged between the New York Central Railroad (NYCR) and the Erie Railroad. At one point, NYCR charged only a dollar per car for the transport of cattle. While the cattle cars quickly filled up, management were dismayed to find that Erie Railroad had also invested in the cattle-haulage business, making Erie a buyer of cattle transport, and thus profiting from NYCR's losses.[69]

Sowell argues:

It is a commentary on the development of antitrust law that the accused must defend himself, not against actual evidence of wrongdoing, but against a theory which predicts wrongdoing in the future. It is the civil equivalent of "preventive detention" in criminal cases—punishment without proof.[67]

Support

edit

An article written by heterodox economist Thomas DiLorenzo and published by the libertarian Cato Institute suggests that while a company might be able to successfully price other firms out of the market, there is no evidence to support the theory that the virtual monopoly could then raise prices. This would be due to other emerging firms rapidly entering the market to compete.[66] Such entrances demand substantial capital investments, which would not be repaid for a substantial period of time due to sharp price decreases, provoked by resumption of competition.[70][71] According to the Chicago School of Thought advocated by Robert Bork, predatory pricing is not always anti-competitive even if it ends a successful strategy.[72] The Court in Post Danmark agreed predatory pricing does not always harm competition because competing "on the merits" to exclude less-efficient competitors can benefit consumers by providing lower prices, improved quality and choice of products and services.[73]

The DG Competition's 'Discussion Paper' states predatory pricing can sometimes be justified as a rational strategy.[74] This is why dominant firms can rebut presumptions of predatory pricing, despite prices falling below the "relevant cost benchmark". For example, dominant undertaking could argue that changing market conditions have caused reduced demand but increased capacity, and therefore below-cost pricing was necessary in the short-term to sell off fresh produce.[75] Although this defense is not commonly accepted due to predatory pricing rarely being the most efficient option, it is still possible for predatory pricing to be considered a rational strategy.[76]

Examples of alleged predatory pricing

edit
  • In AKZO v Commission, AKZO were fined €10 million for abusing its dominant position in the organic peroxides market by reducing its prices to loss-making levels, preventing English firm 'ECS' from competing on the polymer market.[77]
  • In Tetra Pak v Commission, Tetra Pak were fined €75 million for abusing its dominant position by reducing prices of non-asceptic cartons.[78]
  • In Wanadoo Interactive, a €10.35 million fine was imposed on France Télécom's subsidiary, Wanadoo Interactive.[79] Based on AKZO, high-speed residential broadband internet services were priced at levels below AVC until August 2001, and later at around AVC but below ATC.[80]
  • In ACCC v Cabcharge Australia Ltd, Cabcharge were fined $3 million for engaging in predatory pricing conduct by supplying taxi meters that were below cost and fare schedule updates at no charge.[81] This breached section 46(1) of the Trade Practices Act 1974.
  • In MCX v NSE, the NSE abused its dominant position in the currency derivatives segment by waiving transaction and admission fees, thus preventing MCX from competing in the market.[82] This breached section 4 of the Competition Act, 2002 and amounted to a Rs 55.5 crore penalty.
  • According to an AP article[83] a law in Minnesota forced Walmart to increase its price for a one-month supply of the prescription birth control pill Tri-Sprintec from $9.00 to $26.88.
  • According to a New York Times article[84] the German government ordered Walmart to increase its prices.
  • According to an International Herald Tribune article,[85] the French government ordered amazon.com to stop offering free shipping to its customers because it violated French predatory pricing laws. After Amazon refused to obey the order, the government proceeded to fine them €1,000 per day. Amazon continued to pay the fines instead of ending its policy of offering free shipping. After a law was created explicitly banning free shipping, Amazon started charging one cent for delivery.[86]
  • In a period known as Darlington Bus War in Darlington, England, Stagecoach Group offered free bus rides to put the rival Darlington Corporation Transport out of business.[citation needed][87][88][89][90]
  • Some have accused Amazon of using predatory pricing to undercut competitors such as Quidsi before offering to buy them out at low cost once their financial future had become bleak.[91]
  • Sir Freddie Laker, founder of Laker Airways, sued IATA member airlines British Airways, BCal, Pan Am, TWA, Lufthansa, Air France, Swissair, KLM, SAS, Sabena, Alitalia and UTA for conspiracy to put his airline out of business by predatory pricing. They settled out of court for US$50 million, with British Airways later agreeing to contribute a further $35 million. British Airways also reached a separate out-of-court agreement with Sir Freddie personally for £8 million.

See also

edit

References

edit
  1. ^ "Glossary of Statistical Terms". OECD. January 3, 2002. Archived from the original on August 6, 2020. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  2. ^ "Guidance on the Commission's Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings". European Commission. February 24, 2009. Paragraph 63. Archived from the original on March 19, 2020. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  3. ^ "Predatory Pricing" (PDF). OECD. 1989. Archived (PDF) from the original on September 3, 2020. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  4. ^ FDIC Consumer Compliance Examination Manual (PDF). June 2019. pp. II - 2.1. Archived (PDF) from the original on 2021-03-20. Retrieved 2020-11-04.
  5. ^ Funk, Michael (25 July 2018). "The More Economic Approach To Predatory Pricing" (PDF). Journal of Competition Law & Economics. 14 (2): 292–310. doi:10.1093/joclec/nhy008 – via Advanced Access publication.
  6. ^ Ursic, Micaheal L. (1994). "Using Price as a Weapon: An Economic and Legal Analysis of Predatory Pricing". Industrial Marketing Management. 23: 125–131. doi:10.1016/0019-8501(94)90013-2 – via Elsevier Science Inc.
  7. ^ Case 202/07 P Archived 2021-03-09 at the Wayback Machine, France Télécom SA v Commission of the European Communities [2009] ECR I-02369, para 111
  8. ^ a b Case 62/86 Archived 2021-03-08 at the Wayback Machine, AKZO Chemie BV v Commission of the European Communities [1991] ECR I-03359, para 71
  9. ^ Case 333/94 P Archived 2021-03-08 at the Wayback Machine, Tetra Pak International SA v Commission of the European Communities [1996] ECR I-5951, para 44
  10. ^ a b c "Guidance on the Commission's Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings". European Commission. February 24, 2009. Paragraph 71. Archived from the original on March 19, 2020. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  11. ^ "WTO | Anti-dumping - Technical Information". www.wto.org. Retrieved 2023-04-24.
  12. ^ a b c Case 62/86 Archived 2021-03-08 at the Wayback Machine, AKZO Chemie BV v Commission of the European Communities [1991] ECR I-03359, para 72
  13. ^ Wanadoo Interactive (Case COMP/38.233 Archived 2021-03-08 at the Wayback Machine) Commission decision of 16 July 2003, para 271
  14. ^ Case 85/76 Archived 2021-03-08 at the Wayback Machine, Hoffmann-La Roche & Co. AG v Commission of the European Communities [1979] ECR II-00461, para 91
  15. ^ Salop, S.C (1986). "Predatory pricing: Strategic Theory and Legal Policy". Antitrust Law Journal. 56 (2): 253–293.
  16. ^ Ekaterina, Rousseva (2010). Rethinking Exclusionary Abuses in EU Competition Law. Hart Publishing. p. 408. ISBN 9781841139265.
  17. ^ Jones, Alison; Sufrin, Brenda; Dunne, Niamh (2019). Jones & Sufrin's EU Competition Law: Text, Cases, and Materials. Oxford University Press. p. 398. ISBN 9780198824657.
  18. ^ Easterbrook, Predatory Strategies, supra note 1 at 264, 333-37
  19. ^ a b Areeda, Phillip; Turner, Donald (1975). "Predatory Pricing and Related Practices under Section 2 of the Sherman Act". Harvard Law Review. 88 (4): 697–733. doi:10.2307/1340237. JSTOR 1340237.
  20. ^ ECS/AKZO (IV/30.698 Archived 2021-03-08 at the Wayback Machine) Commission decision of 14 December 1985, para 76
  21. ^ Case 62/86 Archived 2021-03-08 at the Wayback Machine, AKZO Chemie BV v Commission of the European Communities [1991] ECR I-03359, para 65
  22. ^ ECS/AKZO (IV/30.698 Archived 2021-03-08 at the Wayback Machine) Commission decision of 14 December 1985, para 79
  23. ^ Case 333/94 P Archived 2021-03-08 at the Wayback Machine, Tetra Pak International SA v Commission of the European Communities [1996] ECR I-5951, para 41
  24. ^ Case 202/07 P Archived 2021-03-09 at the Wayback Machine, France Télécom SA v Commission of the European Communities [2009] ECR I-2369, para 8
  25. ^ Case 209/10 Archived 2021-03-08 at the Wayback Machine, Post Danmark A/S v Konkurrencerådet [2012] EU:C:2012:172, para 44
  26. ^ Richard A. Posner, Antitrust Law. An economic Perspective (University of Chicago Press, 1976), 189
  27. ^ Richard Posner, Antitrust Law: An Economic Perspective 189-190 (1976)
  28. ^ "Guidance on the Commission's Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings". European Commission. February 24, 2009. Paragraph 26. Archived from the original on March 19, 2020. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  29. ^ Case C-23/14 Archived 2020-08-06 at the Wayback Machine, Post Danmark A/S v Konkurrencerådet EU:C:2015:651, para 52
  30. ^ Whish, Richard; Bailey, David (2018). Competition Law. Oxford University Press. p. 763. ISBN 9780198779063.
  31. ^ William J. Baumol, „Predation and the logic of the average variable cost test“, journal of law and economics vol 39, No 1 (1996)
  32. ^ Quasi -Permanence of Price Reductions: A Policy for Prevention of Predatory Pricing, 89 Yale Law Journal 1 (1979).
  33. ^ Raimundas Moisejevas, Ana Novosad, Virginijus Bitė, supra note 31: 592.
  34. ^ Craswell, R & Fratrik, M R 1986, 'Predatory Pricing Theory Applied: The Case of Supermarkets vs. Warehouse Stores,' Case Western Reserve Law Review, vol. 36, no. 1, pp. 1-49, viewed 1 May 2022, <https://scholarlycommons.law.case.edu/caselrev/vol36/iss1/3 Archived 2021-06-21 at the Wayback Machine>.
  35. ^ Craswell, R & Fratrik, M R 1986, 'Predatory Pricing Theory Applied: The Case of Supermarkets vs. Warehouse Stores,' Case Western Reserve Law Review, vol. 36, no. 1, pp. 1-49, viewed 1 May 2022, <https://scholarlycommons.law.case.edu/caselrev/vol36/iss1/3 Archived 2021-06-21 at the Wayback Machine>
  36. ^ Carrier, MA 2019, 'The Four-Step Rule of Reason,' Antitrust, vol. 33, no. 3, pp. 50-51, viewed 2 May 2022, < https://www.antitrustinstitute.org/wp-content/uploads/2019/04/ANTITRUST-4-step-RoR.pdf Archived 2022-04-17 at the Wayback Machine>
  37. ^ Carrier, MA 2019, 'The Four-Step Rule of Reason,' Antitrust, vol. 33, no. 3, pp. 50-51, viewed 2 May 2022, < https://www.antitrustinstitute.org/wp-content/uploads/2019/04/ANTITRUST-4-step-RoR.pdf Archived 2022-04-17 at the Wayback Machine>.
  38. ^ a b Williamson, OE 1977, 'Predatory Pricing: A Strategic and Welfare Analysis,' The Yale Law Journal, vol. 87, no. 2, pp. 284-340, viewed 2 May 2022, < https://www.jstor.org/stable/795652 Archived 2022-05-02 at the Wayback Machine>
  39. ^ Lefever, JT 1981, 'Predatory Pricing Rules: A Comment on Williamson's Output Restriction Rule,' The Yale Law Journal, vol. 90, no. 7, pp. 1639, viewed 2 May 2022, < https://www.jstor.org/stable/796084 Archived 2022-05-02 at the Wayback Machine>
  40. ^ a b Joskow, PL & Klevorick, AK 1979, 'A Framework for Analysing Predatory Pricing Policy,' The Yale Law Journal, vol. 89, no. 2, pp. 213-270, viewed 2 May 2022, < https://www.jstor.org/stable/795837 Archived 2022-05-02 at the Wayback Machine>
  41. ^ "Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209 (1993)". Justia Law. Retrieved 2023-04-24.
  42. ^ Areeda, Hovenkamp, P., H. (2013). "Antitrust Law: An Analysis of Antitrust Principles and Their Application". New York: Wolters Kluwer (4).{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link)
  43. ^ Education. "Tertiary Education Quality and Standards Agency Act 2011". www.legislation.gov.au. Retrieved 2023-04-24.
  44. ^ "Predatory Price". Australian Competition and Consumer Commission Update. 2005. Archived from the original on 29 June 2022. Retrieved 1 November 2020.
  45. ^ Australian Competition & Consumer Commission (ACCC). (2013). Predatory Pricing: A guide to the predatory pricing provisions in the Competition and Consumer Act 2010
  46. ^ Predatory pricing laws shock big operators, ABC Australia, 2007-10-04, archived from the original on 2009-01-13, retrieved 2009-03-16
  47. ^ "Competition Act (R.S.C., 1985, c. C-34)". laws-lois.justice.gc.ca. Archived from the original on 2011-07-16.
  48. ^ "Definition of anti-competitive act". Competition Act (R.S.C., 1985, c. C-34). Department of Justice. Archived from the original on 2017-09-13. Retrieved 2017-09-13.
  49. ^ Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 113 S. Ct. 2578, 2589, vol. 209, 1993, archived from the original on 2012-10-18, retrieved 2006-01-31
  50. ^ "Predatory Pricing: Strategic Theory and Legal Policy". Department of Justice. 25 June 2015. Archived from the original on 7 October 2017. Retrieved 7 October 2017.
  51. ^ "Consolidated Version of the Treaty on European Union and the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union [2008] OJ C115/01, Article 102". May 9, 2008. Archived from the original on May 2, 2020. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  52. ^ "Guidance on the Commission's Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings". European Commission. February 24, 2009. Paragraph 7. Archived from the original on March 19, 2020. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  53. ^ "Guidance on the Commission's Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings". European Commission. February 24, 2009. Paragraph 23. Archived from the original on March 19, 2020. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  54. ^ "Guidance on the Commission's Enforcement Priorities in Applying Article 82 of the EC Treaty to Abusive Exclusionary Conduct by Dominant Undertakings". European Commission. February 24, 2009. Paragraph 24. Archived from the original on March 19, 2020. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  55. ^ Jones, Alison; Sufrin, Brenda; Dunne, Niamh (2019). Jones & Sufrin's EU Competition Law: Text, Cases, and Materials. Oxford University Press. p. 374. ISBN 9780198824657.
  56. ^ "Manupatra Articles". www.manupatrafast.com. Archived from the original on 2016-12-20. Retrieved 2016-12-12.
  57. ^ Agrawal, A 2021, 'Predatory Pricing and Platform Competition in India,' World Competition, vol. 44, no. 1, pp. 115, viewed 1 May 2022, <https://kluwerlawonline.com/journalarticle/World+Competition/44.1/WOCO2021006 Archived 2022-04-25 at the Wayback Machine>.
  58. ^ "Статья 10. Запрет на злоупотребление хозяйствующим субъектом доминирующим положением / КонсультантПлюс". www.consultant.ru. Archived from the original on 2018-04-30. Retrieved 2018-04-28.
  59. ^ "Competition Act 1998". www.legislation.gov.uk. Archived from the original on 2018-04-30. Retrieved 2018-04-28.
  60. ^ (OGH 9.10.2000,ÖBI 2001,135 – subscription prices ; OGH 16.12.2002, 16 Ok 11/02 –Red Bull)
  61. ^ OGH 9.9.1997,36 –film hire;OGH 17.3.1998,ÖBI 1998,356.
  62. ^ OGH 10.7.2001 ÖBI 2001,127 best offer
  63. ^ Ejler Bruun at al., Fogedsager (2nd edn 2000), pp 635 et seq., B, von Eyben et al., Karnovs Lovsamling (2001) p. 3944
  64. ^ Art 1(1) of I. 703/1977
  65. ^ Swedish Competition Authority. (n.d.). Prohibited agreements. Retrieved from https://www.konkurrensverket.se/en/law--guidance/prohibited-agreements/
  66. ^ a b Thomas DiLorenzo. "The Myth of Predatory Pricing". Cato Institute. Archived from the original on February 23, 1997.
  67. ^ a b Sowell, Thomas (May 3, 1999). "Predatory prosecution". Forbes. Archived from the original on July 29, 2017. Retrieved September 8, 2017.
  68. ^ J. Gregory Sidak, Debunking Predatory Innovation, 83 COLUM. L. REV. 1121, 1121 (1983).
  69. ^ Maury Klein. The Life and Legend of Jay Gould.
  70. ^ Harold Demsetz (October 14, 1997). The Economics of the Business Firm: Seven Critical Commentaries. Cambridge University Press. p. 147. ISBN 9780521588652. Archived from the original on June 29, 2022. Retrieved December 25, 2021 – via Google Books.
  71. ^ R. Perman. "Chapter 7. Monopoly and barriers to entry". MBM Business economic notes.[dead link]
  72. ^ Bork, Robert (1993). The Antitrust Paradox: A Policy At War With Itself. Simon & Schuster. p. 148. ISBN 0029044561.
  73. ^ Case 209/10 Archived 2021-03-08 at the Wayback Machine, Post Danmark A/S v Konkurrencerådet [2012] EU:C:2012:172, para 22
  74. ^ "DG Competition Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82 of the Treaty to Exclusionary Abuses" (PDF). Brussels: European Commission. 2005. Paragraph 130. Archived (PDF) from the original on June 23, 2020. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  75. ^ "DG Competition Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82 of the Treaty to Exclusionary Abuses" (PDF). Brussels: European Commission. 2005. Paragraph 131. Archived (PDF) from the original on June 23, 2020. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  76. ^ "DG Competition Discussion Paper on the Application of Article 82 of the Treaty to Exclusionary Abuses" (PDF). Brussels: European Commission. 2005. Paragraph 133. Archived (PDF) from the original on June 23, 2020. Retrieved April 22, 2020.
  77. ^ Case 62/86 Archived 2021-03-08 at the Wayback Machine, AKZO Chemie BV v Commission of the European Communities [1991] ECR I-03359, para 10
  78. ^ Case 333/94 P Archived 2021-03-08 at the Wayback Machine, Tetra Pak International SA v Commission of the European Communities [1996] ECR I-5951, para 52
  79. ^ Wanadoo Interactive (Case COMP/38.233 Archived 2021-03-08 at the Wayback Machine) Commission decision of 16 July 2003, para 409
  80. ^ Wanadoo Interactive (Case COMP/38.233 Archived 2021-03-08 at the Wayback Machine) Commission decision of 16 July 2003, para 257
  81. ^ ACCC v Cabcharge Australia Ltd [2010] FCA 1261 [34]
  82. ^ MCX Stock Exchange Ltd v National Stock Exchange of India Ltd and Ors, Case No. 13/2009
  83. ^ Target matches WalMart's drug cuts; state law limits discounts, Associated Press, September 29, 2007, archived from the original on 2009-04-26, retrieved 2009-03-16
  84. ^ Edmund L. Andrews (September 9, 2000), "Germany Says Wal-Mart Must Raise Prices", New York Times, archived from the original on 2013-03-07, retrieved 2009-03-16
  85. ^ Victoria Shannon (January 14, 2008), Amazon.com is challenging French competition law, International Herald Tribune, archived from the original on 2008-01-15, retrieved 2009-03-16
  86. ^ "Amazon snubs French free delivery ban with one-cent charge". France 24. July 11, 2014. Archived from the original on October 14, 2017. Retrieved October 14, 2017.
  87. ^ Areeda, Phillip E; Hovenkamp, Herbert (2002), Antitrust Law (2nd ed.), pp. 723–745
  88. ^ Cabral, Luis M. B. (2000), Introduction to Industrial Organisation, MIT Press, p. 269
  89. ^ Jones, Alison & Sufrin, Brenda (2007), EC Competition Law (3rd ed.), OUP, pp. 443–473
  90. ^ McGee, John (April 1958), "Predatory Price Cutting: The Standard Oil (N.J.) Case", Journal of Law and Economics, 1: 137–169, doi:10.1086/466547, S2CID 153539977
  91. ^ Mattioli, Dana (22 December 2020). "How Amazon Wins: By Steamrolling Rivals and Partners". Wall Street Journal. Archived from the original on 27 December 2020. Retrieved 27 December 2020.

EU Primary Sources Cited

edit
  • Article 102 TFEU
  • ECS/AKZO (IV/30.698) Commission decision of 14 December 1985
  • Case 202/07 P, France Télécom SA v Commission of the European Communities [2009] ECR I-2369
  • Case 85/76, Hoffmann-La Roche & Co. AG v Commission of the European Communities [1979] ECR II-00461
  • Case 209/10, Post Danmark A/S v Konkurrencerådet [2012] EU:C:2012:172Case 333/94 P, Tetra Pak International SA v Commission of the European Communities [1996] ECR I-5951
  • Case 62/86, AKZO Chemie BV v Commission of the European Communities [1991] ECR I-03359
  • Case C-23/14, Post Danmark A/S v Konkurrencerådet EU:C:2015:651
  • Wanadoo Interactive (Case COMP/38.233) Commission decision of 16 July 2003

Works cited

edit
edit